Modern Economy, 2011, 2, 266-278
doi:10.4236/me.2011.23030 Published Online July 2011 (http://www.SciRP.org/journal/me)
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. ME
On the Emergence and Evolution of Economic Complexity
Bernard C. Beaudreau
Department of Economics Université Laval Québec, Québec, Canada
E-mail: bernard.beaudreau@ecn.ulaval.ca
Received January 27, 2011; revised April 12, 2011; acce pte d April 23, 2011
Abstract
This paper examines the emergence and evolution of economic complexity, defined as large-scale specializa-
tion and exchange (LSSE), within the context of a simple coordination game in which communication and
coordination costs (institutions) are modeled explicitly. The commonly held view that complexity in the form
of LSSE (pre- and post-industrial society) emerged and evolved spontaneously (i.e. as a Nash outcome) is
examined critically. Specifically, it is shown that spontaneous-occurring LSSE equilibria are less likely than
coordination-based ones (i.e. with a third party). Various communication and coordination strategies (CCSs)
are examined, the results of which are then used to examine three complexity-increasing periods, namely
ancient Mesopotamia and the first and second industrial revolutions. It is argued that in addition to techno-
logical innovations, all three were characterized by important institutional innovations (CCS) including the
birth of laisser-faire and the rise of the modern-day, vertically- and horizontally-integrated industrial con-
glomerate.
Keywords: Specialization and Exchange, Coordination Equilibria, Ancient and Modern History
1. Introduction
In the Paleolithic era, economic activity was organized
around the tribe/clan with varying degrees of specializa-
tion and exchange. Men hunted, defended the tribe/clan
from attack and crafted tools, while women collected
berries, reared children, and prepared meals/clothing.
Roles were defined by a number of factors, from genetics
to tradition. With the coming of the first civilizations
came a new form of social and economic organization,
one based on a greater degree of specialization and ex-
change. For example, in Mesopotamia, wealth creation
and exchange was organized by the local temple. Goods
and services were stored and traded within the confines
of the temple. The result was a more complex form of
social and economic organization similar to modern-day
market-based economies, with specialized producers, and
specialized traders, the latter operating the equivalent of
modern-day stores.
With this shift came an important increase in eco-
nomic complexity, defined as “the order resulting from
the interactions of many heterogeneous agents” [1]1.
Producers became highly specialized, and complex ex-
change emerged in the form of temple-based exchange.
This raises a number of interesting, and until now, un-
answered questions, namely, why and how did this hap-
pen? What prompted the emergence of economic com-
plexity? Was it spontaneous in nature, or was some form
of communication and coordination required? If commu-
nication and coordination was required, what form did it
take?
Another significant increase in economic complexity
occurred in the 19th century with the coming of industri-
alization [2,3]2. Tasks that had until then had been per-
formed on a small scale (i.e. home production) were now
performed on a large-scale. Overall output increased
manifold. With this came a new communication and co-
ordination strategy (CCS) in the form of rules-based
laisser-faire, replacing what until then had been a discre-
tion-based CCS (i.e. mercantilism). This raises another
set of questions, namely were the two related, and if so,
how? Was the shift to a rules-based CCS a cause or an
effect? Could the first industrial revolution have occurred
1Similarly, Wikipedia defines civilization as “a kind of human society
or culture; specifically, a civilization is usually understood to be a
complex society characterized by the practice of agriculture and settle-
ment in cities.”
2For our purposes, economic complexity will be defined as the extent to
which goods and services are obtained via exchange, as opposed to
autarky. Maximum economic complexity, according to this definition,
occurs when the individual is completely specialized, producing one
good/service (one task), and acquiring all others by exchange.
B. C. BEAUDREAU
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. ME
267
within a discretion-based, hierarchical CCS (i.e. mercan-
tilism)?
These questions are important for a number of reasons.
For one, they are important historically. What prompted
epoch-defining paradigm increases in economic com-
plexity, and what role did communication and coordina-
tion strategies play? What were the corresponding insti-
tutions? How did they emerge and evolve? Second, they
are important theoretically. Can economic complexity
increase spontaneouslythat is, in a Nash senseas is
commonly believed? Or, is it more appropriately mod-
eled as a coordination game? Third, they are important
from a practical point of view. For example, what lessons
does the past have to offer to countries intent on moving
to more complex forms of economic organization. Lastly,
one could argue that a better theoretical and historical
understanding of the emergence of complexity and sub-
sequent innovations in complexity is an invaluable input
in the current debate over institutions and their role in
economic development [4,5].
This paper attempts to address these questions histori-
cally and theoretically. Specifically, it examines the
emergence and evolution of economic complexity, de-
fined as large-scale specialization and exchange (LSSE),
within the context of a Schelling-type coordination game
in which communication and coordination costs are
modeled explicitly. The results are then used to examine
what is largely held to coincide with the emergence and
evolution of economic complexity, namely the birth of
civilization in Mesopotamia and subsequent innovations,
namely the first and second industrial revolutions. The
paper is organized as follows. To begin with, we exam-
ine the literature on specialization and exchange, both at
the firm and economy-wide levels. This provides a segue
into the next section which presents our baseline model,
consisting of a one-shot Schelling specialization-coor-
dination game [6], involving players who choose be-
tween remaining autarkic or specializing. The two re-
sulting Nash equilibria are examined with particular
emphasis on the LSSE equilibrium. As the latter is more
likely in the presence of a third party (i.e. communication
and coordination), we then turn and examine various
communication and coordination strategies (CCSs) with
particular emphasis on the corresponding costs. Integrat-
ing these into the one-shot specialization game provides
us with the evolutionary model of economic complexity
that is then used to study economic complexity histori-
cally. To begin with, we examine the emergence of eco-
nomic complexity in ancient Mesopotamia, specifically
in Sumer and Akkad. This is followed by an account of
the first and second industrial revolutions, both of which
witnessed a marked increase in economic complexity.
Given the role of rules-based CCSs, specifically of lais-
ser faire, in industrialization, we examine various aspects
of what Karl Polanyi refers to as the “Great Transforma-
tion.” We conclude with a discussion of our results, and
a summary of our findings.
2. Production Process Complexity and
Economic Complexity
The study of economic complexity is as old as econom-
ics itself, dating back in time to the French Physiocrats
(e.g. Tableau économique), and to Adam Smith’s An
Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Na-
tions. According to Smith, complexity, while being the
result of new technologies, notably the steam engine,
was determined by the extent of the market. The greater
the extent of the market, the greater the overall level of
specialization (division of labor) in the economy and,
consequently, the greater the level of wealth. Economic
complexity, as such, was technology-driven, but market
determined. Specialization at the firm level according to
Smith required coordination. The latter was the responsi-
bility of the entrepreneur, whose task it was to coordinate
parallel and sequential high-throughput, Boulton-Watts
rotary-drive powered production sub-processes within
the firm. Specialization and mechanization, he argued,
were key determinants of productivity growth, as evi-
denced by the following passage taken from Chapter 1 of
“The Wealth of Nations.”
The great increase in the quantity of work which, in
consequence of the division of labour, the same number
of people are capable of performing, is owing to three
different circumstances; first, to the increase in dexterity
in every particular workman; secondly, to the saving of
the time which is commonly lost in passing from one
species of work to another; and lastly, to the invention of
a great number of machines which facilitate and abridge
labour, and enable one man to do the work of many [7].
According to the classics and neoclassics, coordination
within the firm was the purview of the entrepreneur. Be-
yond him/her, coordination would be carried out by
markets. Just where in-firm coordination ended, and
markets began was not-well understood. Clearly, produc-
tion sub-processes within the firm were coordinated by
the entrepreneur. Anything beyond, it was usually as-
sumed, was left to the market.
The early 20th century witnessed a shift in this frontier,
with an increase in hierarchical, in-house coordination in
the form of highly vertically and horizontally-integrated
firms [8,9]. Increasingly, the invisible hand of the market
was being usurped by the visible hand of hierarchy. This
raised a number of fundamental questions, questions the
profession continues to study to this very day. What
happened? Why the sudden reversal of fortunes? After
B. C. BEAUDREAU
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. ME
268
all, according to basic theory, markets were superior to
hierarchies, or so it was thought. Ronald Coase reframed
the question in terms of transactions costs [10], arguing
that when transactions costs are high, firms internalize
what would otherwise be arms-length transactions. Oth-
ers, including Oliver Williamson, examined various al-
ternative communication and coordination strategies, the
result of which was taxonomy of organizational struc-
tures consisting of four such arrangements: market gov-
ernance, bilateral governance, trilateral governance and
unified governance [11]. Market governance is the pre-
ferred arrangement in the case of recurrent and non-spe-
cific transactions, whereas trilateral governance is used
for occasional and medium specific transactions. Unified
governance is preferred for recurrent and highly-specific
transactions.
The 1990s witnessed a renewed interest in such ques-
tions. This, one could argue, owed to a number of de-
velopments, including the productivity slowdown, and
outsourcing, both of which raised fundamental questions
regarding organizational structure. For example, was
centralization or decentralization more conducive to in-
novation and productivity growth? Outsourcing, some
argued, signaled the start of a new phase in organiza-
tional structure, namely what Richard Langlois referred
to as the “Vanishing Hand”, namely a shift away from
large-scale, integrated industrial conglomerates (hierar-
chy) back to markets [12].
Gary Becker and Kevin M. Murphy’s work on the di-
vision of labor, coordination costs, and knowledge was
one of the earliest attempts at examining the relationship
between the division of labor, coordination and knowl-
edge. Moving away from the Coasian concept of transac-
tions costs, they emphasized coordinating costs, specifi-
cally on the in-firm costs of coordinating specialized and
highly interdependent activities [13]. Similarly, Thomas-
sen and Lorenzen examined the relationship between
coordination mechanisms, specialization of production
activities, information and knowledge, and learning pro-
cesses [14].
Related questions have and continue to be studied in
the organizational behavior literature where the focus is
on the constrained-optimization approach to modelling
the concept of bounded rationality, based largely on
costly communication and coordination. According to
Timothy Van Zandt, constrained-optimal bounded ra-
tionality means that “there are upper limits on agents
ability to communicate and to calculate with information
in the brain” [15,2]. Put differently, firms face commu-
nication constraints and computation constraints, the
presence of which affects organizational structure, plac-
ing a limit on production process complexity, and as
such the division of labor.
This literature has, for the most part, focused on the
division of labor in a partial equilibrium settingthat is,
from the point of view of the individual firm. Recently,
[16-19] examined the “economy-wide” division of labor
as a coordination game where firms decide whether to
specialize or not based on other firms’ strategies and
where markets are assumed to exist. Nonetheless, coor-
dination failures are shown to exist. As it turns out, this
literature assumes the existence of marketsthat is, the
problem studied here has already been resolved3. There
are players (agents) who have specialized in buying,
holding and selling merchandize. The merchant’s prob-
lem (autarky or specialize) is not addressed. A more
complete analysis would have producers specializing in
the presence of markets (specialized traders), but not
otherwise, and the emergence of markets (specialized
traders) in the presence of specialized producers. Put
differently, a player’s decision to specialize would de-
pend on whether other players specialize and whether the
relevant trading institutions exist and vice versa.
Surprisingly little attention has been paid to this prob-
lem, whether from a historical point of view or a theo-
retical point of view. How do (have) societies, in their
pursuit of economic complexity, solve (solved) this “co-
ordination problem.” Did LSSE evolve spontaneously, or
was costly communication and coordination required?
What were the institutions that allowed for large-scale
specialization? Clearly, there were times in the history of
civilization (forms of economic complexity) when plan-
ning (specialization and exchange) dominated, and others
when laisser-faire dominated. For example, throughout
much of ancient and modern history, hierarchies domi-
nated (from Mesopotamia to Rome to Medieval Europe);
for the past two centuries, laisser-faire has dominated.
How and under what circumstances did such LSSE-re-
lated equilibria arise? Was the choice of a communica-
tion and coordination strategy a cause or effect of ep-
och-defining technological change? Clearly, the role of
CCSs in the development of increasingly complex socie-
ties is an important question, historically, theoretically,
and practically (i.e. policy wise).
John Hicks, in A Theory of Economic History, pub-
lished in 1969, raised a similar question, which he re-
ferred to as “specialization upon trade,” to be distin-
3In related work, similar questions have been raised. For example,
Jeremy Greenwood and Bruce Smith examined the emergence of mar-
kets in a world of specialized intermediate goods [20]. Markets, they
argue, are a necessary condition for production technologies requiring
specialized intermediate goods. Rachel Kranton studied a similar ques-
tion, namely the emergence of market exchange [21]. Two modes o
f
exchange are considered, namely reciprocal versus large market ex-
change. Conditions under which large market exchange emerge were
derived. Both forms of exchange, however, assume specialization to
begin with. Agents can either trade in informal markets (exchange) or
in formal markets. An obvious extension would have large-scale spe-
cialization and exchange being derived endogenously.
B. C. BEAUDREAU
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. ME
269
guished from “trading without specialization. [22,23]”
Specialization upon trade refers to the Smithian notion of
“the division of labor” upon “the extent of the market.”
In short, the coordination problem referred to earlier. Just
how various civilizations solved the underlying coordi-
nation problem, he argued, was unknown. Among the
possible communication and coordination strategies, he
posited, were 1) social gatherings (religious festival,
fairs), 2) a command economy, and 3) a mercantile
economy. In the case of social gatherings, specialized
traders emerged in response to arbitrage opportunities. In
the case of a command economy, a “King” or ruler “will
be receiving embassies from neighboring chieftains”, and
will engage in gift-giving. In this case, it is the “king’s
steward” who, over time, evolved into a merchant. Ac-
cording to Hicks:
The steward who is employed upon this task is already
performing, by order, some of the functions of a mer-
chant. If he performs them successfully, so that he is sent
back for repeat performances, he will become specialized
upon his new activity. He is not an independent merchant,
but he is a merchant. He is still a servant of the King; a
servant (like other servants) has become specialized upon
a particular function. Trading, on behalf of his master, is
the function he is called on to perform. [22,30]
Our definition of economic complexity (i.e. LSSE) is
similar to Hick’s, namely, the presence of specialized
producers and specialized merchants. Judging from his
list of probable causes, it is likely that various coordina-
tion and coordination strategies (CCSs) played an inte-
gral part of the emergence and evolution of economic
complexity. We now attempt to formalize this process.
3. Modeling the Emergence and Evolution of
Economic Complexity
In this section, we develop a stylized model of the emer-
gence and evolution of economic complexity, defined as
large-scale specialization and exchange (LSSE). To be-
gin with, we examine LSSE in terms of a one-shot
Schelling-type coordination game [6] involving three
initially-autarkic players [23,24]. The results are then
generalized to the n + 1 player case and communication
and coordination costs are introduced.
3.1. The One-Shot Coordination/Complexity
Game
We begin with the baseline case, involving three players
(I = 1, 2, 3) each of whom produces two goods (i
y and
i
x
). Production technology is relatively simple. Player 1
is assumed to have an absolute advantage in the produc-
tion of y; player 2 in the production of x; player 3 in nei-
ther. In autarky, player output can be denoted as follows,
namely
11
,
y
x,
22
,
y
x, and

33
,
y
x. Absolute ad-
vantage can be formalized as follows: 123
==yyy
and 213
==
x
xx
, where 1
4. As each of the three
players produces both goods in autarky, the resulting
Cobb-Douglas utility levels (payoffs) are 12
111
=Uyx
,
12
222
=Uyx
, and 12
133
=Uyx
, respectively, where
>0, =1.
j

To capture the gains from specialization, we assume
that by specializing, output rises by a factor of
,
where >1
. For example, if Player 1 specializes in
good y, then his output increases to 1
y
. However, for
specialization to occur, a form of organized exchange
(trading institutions) must exist. In our framework, the
relevant trading institution takes the form of a special-
ized trader who buys, holds and sells the two goods i
y
an i
x
[25,26]. For our purposes, we will assume that
Player 3 has an absolute advantage in this activity (i.e.
intermediation). Absolute advantage dictates that Player
1 will specialize in good y and Player 2 in good x, Player
3 in intermediation.
For the sake of analysis, the cost of buying, holding
and selling goods y and x will be expressed in real terms,
specifically as a fraction
1
where

0< <1
of
output. For example, the cost of intermediating 1
y
is
1
1
y
, 1
y
being the net-of-intermediation-
costs quantity of good y available for exchange (i.e. be-
tween Players 1 and 2)5. Next, we assume that the latter
is shared equally among Players 1 and 26. As such, the
corresponding utility levels (payoffs) can be written as

12
11 2
=2 2
s
Uy x

 
,

12
21 2
=2 2
s
Uy x

 
, and
 
12
31 2
=1 1
s
Uyx
 

 
 , respectively.
The relevant game is as follows. Each player chooses
a Nash binary strategy consisting of either the status
quo/autarky (S = 0) or specializing (S = 1). Specialization
and exchange (LSSE) corresponds to the case in which
all three players opt for S = 17. The game begins with the
players choosing S =0. That is, producing and consuming
goods y and x. The question we then ask is relatively
straightforward, namely, can LSSE, defined as the joint
presence of specialized producers and a trader, emerge
spontaneously (i.e. as Nash equilibrium)?
The corresponding payoff matrix is shown in Table 1,
4
, the coefficient of absolute and comparative advantage, is assumed
to be the same across players and across goods. This assumption could
be relaxed without loss of generality.
5
1
1y
and
2
1
x
represent the cost of intermediation.
6This is a simplifying assumption that can be relaxed without affecting
the results.
7In this regard, the model is similar to those found in agent-
b
ased
com
p
utational economics
(
ACE
)
[27].
B. C. BEAUDREAU
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. ME
270
where two separate subcases are presented. In the first,
Player 1 chooses to not specialize. Here, we see that
23
==0SS is the preferred strategy. If Players 2 and 3
nonetheless specialize, their utility falls to zero as there
is no good y available on the market (i.e. to purchase).
When Player 1 specializes (Subcase 2), specialization
will be the preferred Nash strategy on the part of the two
other players when >2
 
and

1>2

8.
Put differently, for specialization to be a preferred strat-
egy, it must be the case that specialization on the part of
Players 1 and 2 more than compensates the loss of output
that accompanies the creation of trade institutions, in this
case, Player 3 becoming a specialized trader. It turns out
that 12 3
===0SSS and 123
===1SSS are the only
two Nash equilibria. If the three players choose autarky
to begin with, then LSSE is not possible. However, if
they choose specialization, LSSE emerges.
Consider the off-diagonal terms. If Players 1 and 2
choose autarky, and Player 3 chooses to specialize, then
the payoffs are 12
11
y
x
, 12
22
y
x
, and 0, respectively.
Player 3 is worse off as a result. This illustrates the un-
derlying incentive structure. Starting from a position of
autarky, there are no private (Nash) incentives to spe-
cialize. Notwithstanding the case in which the players
simultaneously choose to specialize initially, LSSE is
unlikely in a relevant Nash game. This, however, is not the
case in the corresponding cooperative-strategy game,
where the three cooperate and play 12
==SS 3=1S
thus moving to the Pareto-dominant LSSE equilibrium.
These results are easily generalized to the case of n + 1
players and n goods. In this case, LSSE will be a domi-
nant Nash/Cooperative strategy if

1>
nnn

and

1>n

. All off-diagonal entries in the relevant n
+ 1 by n + 1 payoff matrix will be analogous to those in
Table 1. Specialization in this case has to be such that
each individual producer, of which there are n, serves the
entire market for his/her good, and the n + 1 player be-
comes the specialized trader, in this case buying, holding
and selling n goods. To summarize, for economic com-
plexity, defined here as 123 1
==,, =1
n
SSS S
, to
emerge, two sets of conditions must be met, namely

1>
nnn

and

1>n

(technology condi-
tions) and coordination (coordination condition). The for-
mer refers to the various parameter values

,,,

while the latter refers to players’ cooperative strategy
(equilibria). Notwithstanding the improbable, but not
impossible, Nash LSSE case, both are necessary condi-
tions for the emergence of large scale specialization and
exchange.
Table 1. Payoff matrix.
Subcase 1: S1 = 0
2\3 S3 = 0 S3 = 1
S2 = 012
11
yx
, 12
22
yx
, 12
33
yx
12
11
yx
, 12
22
yx
,0
S2 = 112
11
yx
,0, 12
33
yx
12
11
yx
, 0,0
Subcase 2: S1 = 1
2\3 S3 = 0 S3 = 1
S2 = 00, 12
22
yx
, 12
33
yx
0, 12
22
yx
,0
S2 = 10, 0, 12
33
yx

12
12
22yx
 
,

12
12
22yx

,
 
12
12
11yx
 



The next step is to model what we refer to as “institu-
tional coordination” explicitlythat is, third-party coor-
dination [23]. We have shown thus far that LSSE re-
quires not only non-negligible productivity gains from
specialization, but also the emergence of a specialized
trader (Player 3) who coordinates (organizes) trade (buy,
hold and sell). It is important to point out that such ac-
tivities do not contribute directly to welfare (i.e. enter the
utility function), but yet are nonetheless necessary. Not-
withstanding the case in which LSSE emerges sponta-
neously (the probability of which diminishes with n, the
number of players), large-scale coordination is also nec-
essary. Like all other activities, it is costly. Players must
establish lines of communication between themselves
and decide on a set of rules for collective decision mak-
ing, all of which is costly. We shall refer to such strate-
gies on the part of players as communication and coor-
dination strategies (CCSs). It is conceivable that these
costs could tip the balance in favor of autarky. That is,
CCS costs could make autarky the evolutionary stable
strategy despite non-negligible gains from specialization
and exchange. To model this explicitly, we now turn and
model LSSE in the presence of CCS costs.
3.2. Communication and Coordination
Strategies
Two broad types of strategies will be considered. The
first are discretionary CCSs, where equilibria (e.g.
=1,2,,
i
Si n
) are arrived at by unanimous consent
(unanimity game), and players commit9. Entry may or
may not be controlled (i.e. require consent). The second
are rules-based CCSs, where players, again by way of
consent, unanimously adopt a set of rules that, once in
place, govern behavior (i.e. i
S). Communication and
coordination strategies (CCSs) can as such range from a
9These assumptions can be relaxed without affecting the results. For
example, majority rule or any other less-than-unanimity rules could be
invoked as the relevant decision criterion.
8These conditions were derived by equating

12
11
22yx

to 12
11
yx
, and
 
12
33
11yx




to 12
33
yx
, and solv-
ing for F

,, 0


12
==12

.
B. C. BEAUDREAU
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. ME
271
highly unstructured decision-making unit (distributed
CCS) to a hierarchical management structure (e.g. hier-
archical CCS), to a set of rules (e.g. rules-based CCS), or
lastly, to some combination thereof.
Formally, a communication and coordination strategy
provides each of the players with the necessary informa-
tion and decisional framework withing which to coordi-
nate their strategies (i.e. i
S) [28,29]. Drawing from sim-
ple network design theory, we assume that communica-
tion and coordination requires the establishment of a link
between two players, one that allows for the exchange of
information on preferences, coordination possibilities,
technology and strategies. In the n player case, there
are a total of

12nn


pairwise links. This de-
scribes the baseline case, namely the distributed CCS,
where there are

12nn


pairwise links. The cost
function of maintaining each link is
=,,dml

which is increasing in d is the average geographical
distance between any two players (taken pairwise), ml
is the number of goods and services (m) multiplied by
l, the average number of sub-processes per good/service,
and
, the uncertainty associated with a given technol-
ogy (or new technology)10. Accordingly, the further apart
players are geographically on average, the higher are
communication and coordination costs. The more goods
and services there are, and the more sub-processes (l)
there are per good/service, the greater is the cost of
communication and coordination (vertical and horizontal
information flows and decision trees). The more complex
is a technology (product and process), the higher is the
cost of communication and coordination. Lastly, the cost
of communication and coordination per link is increasing
in the ex-ante uncertainty associated with a new tech-
nology. The associated uncertainty raises the costs of
communication and coordination and may preempt
technological change11. The corresponding average (per
player) cost of communication and coordination in the
distributed CCS case is

,, 12dml n

. Note that
in this case, the average cost increases with the group
size, and with product and process uncertainty.
Consider next the case of the hierarchical CCS, where
the players begin by choosing a leader (gatekeeper),
referred to as the nth player. Once chosen, s/he coordi-
nates information flows and decision making, going
between the other 1n players12. Costs differ. First,
there is the cost of choosing the coordinator/gatekeeper,
,,12dml nn

. Then, there is the cost of
communicating and coordinating in the presence of the
gatekeeper,
,, 1dml n

. The cost of choosing a
gatekeeper is a one-time cost; however, the cost of
communicating and coordinating is a recurrent cost
which, as shown, is an increasing function of n, the
number of players13. It stands to reason that the longer
the game is played, the more advantageous it is to opt for
a hierarchical CCS over a distributed CCS. While the
hierarchical CCS is, over time, less costly than the dis-
tributed CCS, both are discretionary forms of communi-
cation and coordination, and, as, such, relatively costly.
Each new case (coordination problem) must be consid-
ered individually, and, more importantly, the outcome
(equilibria) must be consensual.
The third CCS considered in this paper is a rules-based
CCS, consisting of the establishment of, and execution of
a set of communication and coordination rules. In this
case, starting from autarky, players initially opt for either
a distributed or hierarchical CCS within which a set of
rules is drafted and adopted, one that could be invoked in
the presence of potential coordination failures. An exam-
ple of a rules-based CCS is the case of an initial resolu-
tion of the coordination failure LSSE (by fiat), followed
by the implementation of a price mechanism with entry
and exit, where price increases signal excess demand,
and price decreases signal excess supply14. Prices and
profits constitute the relevant signalling devices, coordi-
nating the behavior of the n players. Once in place, the
cost of communicating and coordinating activity is rela-
tively low, and, in the limit, zero, abstracting from en-
forcement costs (judicial system).
The fourth and last CCS is a hybrid, consisting of a
rules-Based CCS with local hierarchies. In this case,
each of the m goods is produced within a verti-
cally-integrated (l sub-processes or l stages of value
added), hierarchically organized producers (firms). Within
the latter, communication and coordination is organized
hierarchically (management structures). Examples of these
include large, vertically-integrated “giant firms” [8,9].
Thus far, it has been assumed that outcomes are de-
terministic. That is, a CCS yields the desired outcome
with certainty. While this may be true in the case of sim-
ple coordination problems (simple technology combined
with limited number of players/goods/services), it may
not be the case in the presence of complex problems,
10By technology-related uncertainty, it should be understood the uncer-
tainty associated with a given set of technologies (process and product)
at any given point in time.
11Other factors affecting
, the cost of each link in a communication
and coordination game are variables such as the number of rounds o
f
negotiation required to reach an agreement, as well as the information
costs per round.
12One could define the nth player as a clique [28]. As such, the nth
p
layer deals with all other 1n players, providing information on
p
references, actions, and reactions.
13We implicitly assume that the gatekeeper (i.e. the nth players) does
not incur any additional costs in his/her role. That is, s/he offers coor-
dinating services for free. If we relax this assumption and assume that
s/he has to deploy additional resources, then the resulting costs would
have to be factored in on a recurrent basis.
14This is similar to market simulation exercises in artificial computa-
tional economies (ACE’s), where roles (producers, merchants, con-
sumers) are assigned initially, and are then free to transact in a market
environment.
B. C. BEAUDREAU
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. ME
272
where outcomes are more probabilistic. CCSs may not
yield the Pareto-optimal outcomein fact, they may fail
altogether. This can result from the players’ or the gate-
keeper’s inability to fully understand either the technol-
ogy, or how the technology is best deployed. To capture
this, Column 3 in Table 2 formalizes
, the probability
of success as a function of n, the number of players,
ml , the product of the number of goods/services and the
number of processes per good/service (l), and
, the
overall, aggregate complexity of the technology. Note
that the probability of success in the case of discretionary
CCSs (distributed and hierarchical) is decreasing in both
n, ml and
. Contrast this with rules-based CCSs,
where it is decreasing only in ml and
. Rules-based
CCSs are, as we will attempt to show, better suited to
more complex environments. This is not to say, however,
that success is assured. A rules-based CCS is only as
good as the elements that comprise it. If players are un-
able to fully appreciate a technology’s potential (i.e.
),
then it may not be adopted.
The choice of an initial CCS within which to adopt a
set of rules will be determined by, among other factors,
the very nature of the problem (i.e. simple or complex).
For example, in the case of potentially complex phe-
nomena, a rules-based CCS would minimize costs. That
is, starting from a distributed CCS, they designate a
gatekeeper (i.e. the nth player), and proceed to draft a set
of rules governing the eventual rules-based CCS. In this
case, the hierarchical CCS is transitional in nature, exist-
ing for the sole purpose of setting up rules and resolving
any initial coordination failures. Analytically, the overall
costs of setting up a rules-based CCS consist of

,, 12dml nn



, the cost of the initial distrib-
uted CCS, and
,1dn

, the cost of establishing
rules within the hierarchical CCS15. We assume that

,dn
is considerably greater than

,,dml
, given
the nature of the task at hand, namely, establishing rules.
Put differently, the establishment of rules is more com-
munication and coordination intensive than establishing
a simple coordination strategy (i.e. within the context of
a one-shot coordination game).
Discretion-based CCSs and rules-based CCSs differ
also in so far as strategic behavior is concerned. In a dis-
cretion-based CCS, coalitions and strategic behavior are
possible. As decisions are consensual, strategic behavior
is possible. Players may resist change, whether it be en-
try of new members, or a change in a member’s behav-
ior16. For example, a coalition of players can block the
introduction of a new technology that would potentially
decrease the value of their assets. Such behavior cannot,
however, arise in rules-based CCS.
Table 2 summarizes the costs as well as the risks as-
sociated with the four CCSs described here. We see, for
example, that the distributed CCS has no initial (i.e.
fixed) costs, but high recurrent costs. This owes to the
lack of a structured environment. These costs are lower
in the hierarchical CCS case. It, however, requires an
initial fixed cost of
 
,, 12dml nn



, to choose
a “coordinator.” Recurrent communication and coordina-
tion costs are zero in the case of the rules-based CCS.
The initial costs of the latter, however, are greater than
either of the two discretionary CCSs. Lastly, rules-based
CCSs with local hierarchies have recurrent communica-
tion and coordination costs (i.e. the cost of large-scale
organizational hierarchies-Alfred Chandler’s visible
hand”), defined as
lq
, where

l
corresponds to
the cost of a management hierarchy in the presence of l
sub-processes, and q corresponds to the number of lo-
cal hierarchies (i.e. giant firms)[30].
The problem of the emergence and evolution of eco-
nomic complexity (LSSE) in the presence of risky and
costly communication and coordination strategies is
formalized in terms of a communication and coordina-
tion cost-augmented payoff matrix, the diagonal ele-
ments of which are shown in Table 3, where
corre-
sponds to the cost, expressed in terms of the n goods of
the relevant communication and coordination strategy for
the n + 1 players17. Clearly, the lower is
, ceteris
paribus the greater the probability that LSSE will emerge
as an evolutionary stable strategy. We see that LSSE is
Table 2. Initial and recurrent CCS costs and probability of success.
CCS\Type Initial Recurrent
Probability (
)
Distributed 0

,,1 2dml nn


1,,nml
Hierarchical

,,1 2dml nn

,, 1dml n


1,,nml
Rules-Based

,,1 2,1dmlnnd n
 
 
 0

1,ml
Rules-Based with Local Hierarchies

,,1 2,1dmlnnd n
 
 

lq

1,ml
15This is analogous to the January 2005 election in Iraq, the stated purpose of which was to elect a slate of candidates who, once in office, would
begin drafting a new constitution.
16A good example of such coalitions is the early 19th century British House of Lords which voted against free-trade.
17Here, it is implicitly assumed that CCS costs are assumed equally by all players. Affecting such costs are the cost of communication and the costs o
f
coordination. The lower are such costs, the lower is
and the greater is the probability that LSSE emerges as the relevant equilibria.
B. C. BEAUDREAU
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. ME
273
Table 3. Diagnonal elements of the CCS-augmented payoff
matrix.
12 1
=== =0
n
SS S
1,
11 1
=1 =1=1
,,,
nn n
ni
ii
iii
iii
yy y

 
12 1
=== =0
n
SSS



=1
=1
=1
1,
1,,
11
ni
ii
i
ni
ii
i
ni
ii
i
yn
yn
y








most likely to emerge when
, the specialization coef
ficient is high,
, the cost of communication and coor-
dination is low, and
, the probability of success, is
high. An
-augmenting technology shock will, in the
presence of a low
, be economic-complexity increas-
ing, and vice-versa. The effect of
, the cost of inter-
mediation, on LSSE is ambiguous, at least in terms of the
payoff matrix. A higher price of intermediation will in-
crease the payoff to the n + 1 player (i.e. the merchant)
vis-à-vis the autarky payoff, but reduce the payoff to
would-be producers (specialized), thus possibly reducing
the probability of LSSE. The more complex is the coor-
dination problem, the lower is
, and the less likely is it
to emerge as a solution to the relevant game. Within this
framework, there exists the very real possibility that new,
potentially-revolutionary, output-increasing technologies
are not adopted owing to prohibitive communication and
coordination costs. Communication acts as a constraint
on coordination and, in turn, coordination acts as a con-
straint on adoption. Conceivably, the overall cost of
communication and coordination could be such that
economic complexity fails to emerge in the presence of
Pareto-improving technological change.
4. LSSE: The Historical Record
These results provide a convenient framework within
which to reexamine the question raised by Hicks, namely
what prompted the emergence and evolution of economic
complexity, defined as large-scale specialization and
exchange (LSSE)specialization upon trade. In this sec-
tion, we examine three cases (periods): the rise of civili-
zation in Mesopotamia, the first industrial revolution and
the second industrial revolution. We begin with the case
of Mesopotamia, the cradle of civilization, the defining
features of which were i) the presence of a large-scale
agriculture (irrigation, draft animals) and manufactures
(specialized artisans) and ii) the presence of specialized
traders and trading institutions (temples and ziggurats)
and iii), the presence of hierarchical political governance
(religious authorities) [31-34]. The relevant question is
how did LSSE emerge in the Tigres and Euphrates valley
in the fourth millennium before the modern era? Chro-
nologically, which came first, the technology (
) or the
temples and ziggurats
,
? Did the emergence of a
new technology lead to a new CCS, or vice versa?
There are a number of possibilities. For example, the
development of large-scale religion (ziggurats and priests)
by providing the necessary CCS, led to the development
of large-scale agriculture, leading to the ensuing eco-
nomic complexity. Or conversely, the development of
religion, by providing the necessary CCS, allowed for
the application of an existing (known) technology,
namely large-scale agriculture. In other words, the tech-
nology of large-scale agriculture predated the fourth
millennium, but was not implemented for lack of the
necessary CCS. Another possibility is that the develop-
ment of agriculture (i.e. technology shock) contributed to
the development of a CSS in the form of large-scale re-
ligion (ziggurats and priests). Causality in this case runs
from the technology shock to the organization shock.
The last possibility has the development of agriculture
providing the necessary impetus for the application of an
existing technology in the form of large-scale religion.
Of the four, the second appears to be the most likely,
namely that the development of large-scale religion (or-
ganization) provided the necessary CCS for the applica-
tion of what was then a known technology in the form of
large-scale agriculture. There is considerable evidence
that basic agricultural techniques (sowing, cultivating,
and reaping) predated Mesopotamia by a number of mil-
lennia [35]. On the other hand, while religion predated
Mesopotamia by millennia, there is no archaeological
evidence of large-scale religion (i.e. large temples/zig-
gurats) in the upper-Paleolithic era).
What is clear from our model is that large-scale agri-
culture (LSSE) required large-scale religion (CSS), and
large-scale religion required large-scale agriculture. In
addition to providing religious services on a large scale,
the temple priests of Mesopotamian cities (e.g. Sumer,
Akkad) provided the necessary communication and co-
ordination strategy (CCS) and trade institutions (special-
ized traders), thus lowering both
, and
, the cost of
intermediation and the cost of communication and coor-
dination, respectively, and raising
, the probability of
success. Evidence of the integral role of the temple in the
economic affairs (e.g. record keeping, writing, weights
and measures, money, and codified civil law) of Meso-
potamian cities is well documented [33,36,37] 18. Next,
we examine the evolution of economic complexity de-
fined as the continued specialization and exchange in
response to technology shocks. We will be particularly
interested in two well-known technology shocks (general
18Anecdotally, we know that virtually all great civilizations were liter-
ally and figuratively built around religion, in the form of temples.
Large-scale temples, specialization and exchange appear to go
hand-in-hand.
B. C. BEAUDREAU
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. ME
274
purpose technologies), namely the steam engine (first
industrial revolution) and the electric motor (second in-
dustrial revolution), each of which contributed to in-
creasing economic complexity [38,39].
The Neolithic era witnessed a paradigm shift in the
level of economic complexity, characterized by LSSE.
Exchange became a staple in the cities of Mesopotamia,
Egypt, China, India, Greece, and Rome. However, it was
nonetheless limited. Not all wealth (goods and services)
was traded [40]. In the 17th century Great Britain, the
bulk of economic activity was autarkic in nature, con-
sisting mainly of small-scale, self-sufficient agriculture.
Like in other European countries at the time, there did,
nonetheless, exist, a more evolved form of economic
activity, commonly referred to as mercantilism, which
consisted of small-scale specialization and exchange,
organized and controlled, for the most part, by govern-
ment. Licences (rights) to produce and to trade were is-
sued by royal edict, as were prices.
While allowing for a certain degree of complexity, this
CCS proved, in time, to be unworkable, and the underly-
ing cause of a shift to a new CCS, namely laisser-faire.
Laisser-faire, we shall argue, was a response not to the
shortcomings of mercantilism per se, but, rather, to the
shortcomings of mercantilism in the presence of a para-
digm technology shock in the form of the steam engine.
The steam engine provided the potential for heightened
economic complexity (i.e. an increase in
and a de-
crease in
). Factories would replace what at the time
was small-scale, artisanal production (putting-out sys-
tem), resulting in a manifold increase in potential output
estimated by Robert Owen estimated the order of mag-
nitude to be 40, David Ricardo, to be 20 [41,42]. Rail-
roads reduced transportation costs, thus lowering
.
Greater economic complexity was now feasible. What’s
more, while innovations in the Neolithic era had in-
creased output in a handful of sectors (tool making, ag-
riculture), the steam engine offered the possibility of
increased output in many sectors of the economy [43].
Could Great Britain in the late 18th century make the
transition to the new, higher LSSE equilibrium? More to
the point, could it make the transition within a hierarchi-
cal CCS? Could the Lords, Monarchy, and Prime Minis-
ter coordinate the implementation of the new process
technology, one characterized by a far greater division of
labor (higher l), massive investment in capital equip-
ment, increased coordination between the stages of pro-
duction (division of labor), and a more extensive distri-
bution (sales) network. Technically, the cost of coordina-
tion skyrocketed. Referring to Tabl e 2 , greater values for
n, m and l, increases the recurrent cost of discre-
tionary, hierarchical CCS. Add to this the uncertainty
associated with the new technology and stakeholder iner-
tia (i.e. the various workers’ guilds opposed mechaniza-
tion) and you get a tenuous outcome.
This contributed to a shift to a rules-based CCS in the
form of laisser-faire. Rules as opposed to discretion, its
architects argued, would guide resource allocation. Entry
and exit would be freein the sense of free of govern-
ment. Output and pricing decisions would be made by
the “market.” Risk and uncertainty would be assumed by
investors and entrepreneurs. This is not to say that all
potentially-viable output and exchange opportunities
would be realized, but rather that the probability that
they would be realized would be greater [44]. If for some
reason no one is willing to bring a new process or prod-
uct to market, then even laisser-faire will fail. In this
sense, free markets are a necessary, but not sufficient
condition.
This, we argue, helps explain the preponderant role
assigned to the entrepreneur in both classical and
neo-classical political economy. The success or failure of
a new technology (product and/or process) depends on
his/her ability, on his/her vision, on his/her propensity to
take risks. In a rules-based CCS, the entrepreneur is the
key cog, whereas in a hierarchical CCS, it is the gate-
keeper (e.g. government). The classics and neoclassics
opined that the former outperformed the latter, without,
however, actually proving it. The transition to laisser
faire in Great Britain was not seamless. Hierarchical co-
ordination was not abandoned altogether in favor of
markets and entrepreneurs as evidenced by the continued
presence of large, vertically-integrated firms. The British
East India Company and the Hudson’s Bay Company are
cases in point. Clearly, in these cases, discretion-based
hierarchical coordination must have dominated rules-
based laisser-faire; otherwise, such companies would
have been dismantled, and sold off. Metaphorically, the
visible hand gave way to the invisible hand directing
atomistic as well as highly-integrated firms, the latter
being internally-coordinated [49].
This brings us to the second technology shock, namely
the electric motor (second industrial revolution). The
development of economically-viable electro-magnetic
power ushered in yet another era of heightened economic
complexity. Unlike the steam engine that merely in-
creased throughput rates and lowered unit costs and
prices, electro-magnetic power witnessed the develop-
ment of a whole new set of goods, goods that were elec-
tro-magnetic power based. Examples include refrigera-
tors, vacuums, washer and dryers, radios, automobiles
(affordable) [39]. Potential wealth increased manifold, as
did the underlying CCS uncertainty (i.e.
). Discre-
tionary CCS costs would be prohibitive, and the prob-
ability of success (i.e.
) would be low. Rules-based
CCS costs would be lower; however, the probability of
B. C. BEAUDREAU
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. ME
275
success (i.e.
-Column 3 in Table 3 ) would nonetheless
be low.
The reason is twofold. The introduction of the many
new products and processes made possible by electro-
magnetic power introduced another Schelling-type pro-
ducer-merchant coordination game, involving consumer
durables. Take, for example, mass-produced automobiles.
Who would sell themthe general stores of the time?
Without suitable points of sale (i.e. markets), firms could
not exploit the economies of scale (
) made possible by
electro-magnetic power [45]. For example, the Ford
Motor Company’s Highland Park plant had a rated ca-
pacity of roughly one million automobiles per year. Also,
most these new consumer durables required servicing.
New sales technologies were required (e.g. dealerships),
technologies that were a sine quo non of the second in-
dustrial revolution. As it turns out, the underlying coor-
dination game (producer-merchant) was solved by the
firms themselves as durable good producers established
networks of dealerships to sell and service their products.
Second, the resulting manufacturing processes (ex-
tremely high-throughput) required greater up-stream and
downstream coordination. Feedstocks and intermediate
product flows had to be carefully coordinated. Upstream
suppliers had to invest massively in the new process
technology (electric-powered dynamos). As the historical
record bears witness, the market was unable to provide
the necessary communication and coordination (CCS),
which prompted the emergence of localized hierarchies
in the form of highly vertically-integrated firms [8,9].
Companies such as Ford, General Motors, General Elec-
tric, Singer, and others opted for localized hierarchies.
Ford Motor Company and General Electric integrated
both upstream and down, setting up their own dealer-
ships, complete with financing options (e.g. consumer
credit). Again, the point is that without these localized
hierarchies set against the backdrop of a rules-based CCS
(markets), the second industrial revolution may not have
gotten off the ground.
5. Discussion
Historically, the shift from a discretionary CCS (mercan-
tilism) to a rules-based CCS (free markets), and back to
what essentially are local hierarchies [8,9] in the form of
large, highly-integrated, multi-unit firms, we maintain,
was motivated primarily by what we refer to as coordi-
nation of complexity efficiency considerations than by
basic allocative efficiency considerations. The principal
challenge facing the late 18th century Great Britain was
realizing the heightened economic complexity and
wealth that was synonymous with the steam engine.
Likewise, the principal challenge facing the early 20th
century United States was realizing the heightened eco-
nomic complexity and wealth that was synonymous with
electro-magnetic power (process and product technolo-
gies).
Failure to tailor the CCS to the corresponding tech-
nology complexity can be costly, as evidenced by Brit-
ain’s failure in the late 19th century to implement what
was a home-grown technology, namely electro-magnetic
power. The basic research on electro-magnetism and
hence, the electro-magnetic motorwas carried out in
the 19th century Great Britain by such notables as Mi-
chael Faraday, Charles Wheatstone, Lord Kelvin, Joseph
Swan and others. However, for a number of reasons, the
British failed to implement this new technology, some-
thing that was carried out by Thomas A. Edison and
George Westinghouse in the United States. The Coal
Conservation Sub-Committee, set up by Viscount Hald-
ane in 1916, made numerous references to this “puzzle.”
What had gone wrong? Why had the British failed to
capitalize on what was a home-grown technology. In the
same year, the Board of Trade struck an Electrical
Trades Committee, whose given purpose was to investi-
gate the position of the electrical trades after the war. Sir
Henry Self and Elizabeth Watson summarized its find-
ings as follows:
Reference was made in no uncertain terms to the crip-
pling handicaps of the local and political considerations
which had prevented Great Britain from reaping the
fruits of the outstanding preeminence which it had re-
ceived in original constructive research and development
of electricity generation at the hands of pioneers such as
Faraday, Wheatstone, Kelvin, Swan, Hopkinson, and
many others. The loss of that outstanding lead, the his-
tory of industry in the intervening years, and the evi-
dence taken during their examination of the position led
the Committee to the following conclusions. [46,35]
In other words, local regulation, specifically by the gas
and coal industry, had thwarted the development of the
electric power industry in Great Britain. Rules-based
laisser-faire would have, as it did in the United States,
allowed for the presence of both technologies, with the
spoils going to the winner.
Our results also provide a rationalization of the ex
deus machina, view of the marketthat is, of the market
as an intelligent beingas the optimality of a rules-
based CCS in a dynamic, complex setting, one charac-
terized by on-going technological change (process and
product). As was the case in late 19th century Great Brit-
ain, there may exist a set of processes/products whose
value escapes the grasp of officials (i.e. discretionary
CCSs). In such cases, the communication and coordina-
tion necessary for its implementation is best left to the
“specialists”they are the private individuals who have
B. C. BEAUDREAU
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. ME
276
more information than the n players and gatekeeper in
the hierarchical CCS. A good example of this is FedEx,
the brainchild of Yale undergraduate economics student
Frederick Smith who in the 1960s outlined the idea of an
overnight parcel-delivery service in a term-paper. His
professor, legend has it, didn’t see much merit in the idea,
and gave him a C+. The rest is “history”, so to speak.
Our results also bring into focus many of the issues
raised in the recent institutions-growth literature. This
literature examines the relationship between institutions
and economic growth. For example, [47-52] show cau-
sality running from limited government to economic
growth, while [53,54] show it running in the opposite
direction. [5] provided empirical support for this view
using data on urbanization of European regions during
the last millennium, which showed faster city growth
under more limited governments. Unfortunately, the mi-
crofoundations of this literaturethat is, the underlying
mechanicsare not well developed. Just how institutions
affect growth is not well understood. Our work provides
a framework for understanding the mechanics of gov-
ernance as it relates to economic complexity, and hence
growth. For example, we showed that the key factor in so
far as economic complexity is concerned is not limits on
executive power per se, but rather the limits of executive
power (i.e. the hierarchical CCS) to communicate and
coordinate. There is nothing inherently flawed with ex-
ecutive power; however, as shown, executive power is
limited, both in its ability to understand new technologies,
as well as in its ability to manage complexity. While it is
not impossible for a hierarchical CCS to communicate
and coordinate effectively, thus fostering economic com-
plexity, it is less likely, especially for high values of
,
the complexity of the overall communication and coor-
dination problem. In general, for high values of
, the
less hierarchical is the CCS, the more likely is economic
complexity, and hence, economic growth. This is not to
say that economic complexity cannot arise in a dictator-
ship; however, the likelihood of such an occurrence is
low as s/he would have solve multidimensional commu-
nication and coordination problems. Historically, such
occurrences have been few and far between.
6. Summary and Conclusions
Economic complexity has for the most part been studied
at the firm level, where the emphasis has been on pro-
duction process complexity, specifically, on the division
of labor. In this paper, we examined the question of eco-
nomic complexity, which was defined in terms of LSSE,
focusing on technological change and communication
and coordination costs. Interestingly, our findings are
analogous. Communication and coordination costs act as
a constraint on societies as a whole, hampering in some
cases, preventing in others increases in economic com-
plexity made possible by technology shocks. We main-
tain that this problem was at the heart of Adam Smith’s
magnum opus, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of
the Wealth of Nations, published over two centuries ago.
Getting in the way of increased specialization at the time
(economic complexity) was the extent of the market.
What ensued was an often acrimonious debate over lais-
ser fairethat is over free markets. As we have at-
tempted to show in this paper both communication and
coordination strategies (discretion-based and rules-based)
had their merits and their costs. Discretion-based CCSs,
however, have performed rather poorly in the presence of
new technologies.
While discretion-based CCSs (distributed and hierar-
chical) played an integral role in the emergence and early
evolution of economic complexity, their usefulness had
waned considerably by the 19th century. Attempts at de-
signing discretion-based CCS-based industrial societies
have, not surprisingly, met with little success. Examples
of such societies include the 19th century France, the 20th
century Soviet Union, and Communist China. Based
largely on the writings of Claude Rouvroy, Comte de
St-Simon, the early 19th century France, led by Napoleon,
embarked on an ambitious program of industrialization
organized around a hierarchical CCS. The resulting tech-
nocracy would, in St-Simon’s eyes, close the gap with
Great Britain, and in the process increase economic
complexity. The Soviet Union and China held similar
ambitions. The results are there for all to see. Hierarchi-
cal CCSs have underperformed, relative to comparable
rules-based CCSs, owing to, among others factors, high
information, communication and coordination costs.
As we have attempted to show in this paper, technol-
ogy and technological change are not sufficient condi-
tions for heightened economic complexity and material
wealth. As with all other forms of complexity, organiza-
tion is of equal importance. Heightened specialization
and trade require cost-efficient, highly effective CCSs.
The latter ranged from discretionary CCSs to rules-based
CCSs to combination discretionary-rules-based CCSs.
When it comes to CCSs, no one CCS dominates all oth-
ers. Early innovations in economic complexity were the
result of discretionary, hierarchical CCSs. In time, these
proved to be too costly and ineffective, prompting a shift
to rules-based CCSs in the form of free markets. The
shortcomings (efficiency-wise) of markets, in turn,
prompted the emergence of a hybrid CCS in the form of
localized hierarchies-rules-based CCSs, with large verti-
cally-integrated firms operating in what are free-markets.
These results are interesting for a number of reasons.
First and foremost is their synthetic nature. The theory of
B. C. BEAUDREAU
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. ME
277
economic complexity presented in Sections 2 and 3 syn-
thesizes over two hundred years of political economy
and 6000 years of economic complexity. In doing so,
they refocus the debate surrounding “economic systems”
around dynamic considerations, notably the ability to
coordinate “potential” economic complexity. An inter-
esting by-product is a theory of the origins of large-scale
specialization and exchange (LSSE) as equilibrium to a
Schelling-type coordination game. More often than not,
LSSE required discretionary CCSs, a fact history bears
witness to.
The study of economic complexity is in its infancy.
Much work remains to be done, particularly on CCSs
and their various attributes (costs, efficiency). Another
interesting offshoot is the evolution of CCSs. How did
they evolve over time? What were the underlying issues,
and politics? As it turns out, the history of economic
thought is intimately tied to CCS evolution, with the shift
to rules-based laisser-faire being the equivalent in eco-
nomics of the big-bang in paleontology.
7. References
[1] S. Durlauf, “What Should Policymakers Know About
Economic Complexity?” Working Paper for the SFI
Economics Research Program, 97-10-080, Santa Fe In-
stitute, Santa Fe, 1997.
[2] B. C. Beaudreau, “Energy and the Rise and Fall of Po-
litical Economy,” Greenwood Press, Westport, 1999.
[3] M. Berg, “The Machinery Question and the Making of
Political Economy,” Cambridge University Press, Cam-
bridge, 1980.
[4] E. Glaeser, R. La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes and A.
Shleifer “Do Institutions Cause Growth?” Journal of
Economic Growth, Vol. 9, No. 3, 2004, pp. 271-303.
doi:10.1023/B:JOEG.0000038933.16398.ed
[5] R. la Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes, R. Vishny and A.
Shleifer, “Law and Finance?” Journal of Political Econ-
omy, Vol. 106, No. 6, 1998, pp. 271-303.
[6] T. Schelling, “The Strategy of Conflict,” Harvard Uni-
versity Press, Cambridge, 1960.
[7] A. Smith, “An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the
Wealth of Nations,” Encyclopaedia Britannica, Chicago,
1990 (1776).
[8] A. Chandler, “The Visible Hand: The Revolution in
American Management,” Harvard University Press,
Cambridge, 1977.
[9] R. Sobel, “The Age of Giant: A Microeconomic History
of American Business 1914-1970,” Greenwood Press,
Westport, 1972.
[10] R. Coase, “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, Vol. 4,
No. 16, 1937, pp. 386-405.
doi:10.1111/j.1468-0335.1937.tb00002.x
[11] O. Williamson, “The Economic Institutions of Capitalism:
Firms, Markets and Relational Contracting,” Free Press,
New York, 1985.
[12] R. Langlois, “The Vanishing Hand: The Changing Dy-
namics of Industrial Capitalism,” Industrial and Corpo-
rate Change, Vol. 12, No. 2, 2003, pp. 351-385.
doi:10.1093/icc/12.2.351
[13] G. Becker and K. Murphy, “The Division of Labor, Co-
ordination Costs, and Knowledge,” The Quarterly Jour-
nal of Economics, Vol. 107, No. 4, 1992, pp. 1137-1160.
doi:10.2307/2118383
[14] M. Thomassen and M. Lorenzen, “The Dynamic Costs of
Coordination and Specialization: Production Activities
and Learning Processes in the Danish Construction and
Furniture Industries,” Working Paper, Copenhagen Busi-
ness School, 2001.
[15] T. van Zandt, “Decentralized Information Processing in
the Theory of Organizations,” In: M. Suriel, ed., Con-
temporary Economic Development Reviewed, Vol. 4: The
Enterprise and Its Environment, MacMillan Press, Lon-
don, 1997.
[16] R. P. Gilles and D. Diamantaras, “To Trade or Not to
Trade: Economies with a Variable Number of Trade-
ables,” International Economic Review, Vol. 44, 2003, pp.
1173-1204. doi:10.1111/1468-2354.t01-1-00105
[17] R. P. Gilles and D. Diamantaras, “On the Microeconom-
ics of Specialization,” Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization, Vol. 55, No. 2, 2004, pp. 223-236.
doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2003.07.007
[18] X. K. Yang and Y. K. Ng, “Specialization and Economic
Organization: A New Classical Micro-Economic Frame-
work,” North-Holland, Amsterdam, 1993.
[19] X. K. Yang, “Economics: New Classical Versus Neoclas-
sical Frameworks,” Blackwell Publishing, Malden, 2001.
[20] J. Greenwood and B. D. Smith, “Financial Markets in
Development, and the Development of Financial Mar-
kets,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol.
21, 1997, pp. 145-181.
doi:10.1016/0165-1889(95)00928-0
[21] R. Kranton, “Reciprocal Exchange: A Self-Sustaining
System,” American Economic Review, Vol. 86, No. 4,
1996, pp. 130-151.
[22] J. Hicks, “A Theory of Economic History,” Oxford Uni-
versity Press, London, 1969.
[23] R. Cooper, D. van DeJong, R. Forsythe and T. W. Ross,
“Communication in Coordination Games,” Quarterly
Journal of Economics, Vol. 107, No. 2, 1992, pp. 739-
771. doi:10.2307/2118488
[24] J. V. Huyck, R. Battalio and R. Beil “Tacit Coordination
Games, Strategic Uncertainty, and Coordination Failure,”
American Economic Review, 1990, pp. 234-248.
[25] P. Howitt and R. Clower, “The Emergence of Economic
Organization,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Or-
ganization, Vol. 41, No. 1, 2000, pp. 55-84.
doi:10.1016/S0167-2681(99)00087-6
[26] R. Starr and M. Stinchcombe, “Exchange in a Network of
Trading Posts,” In: G. Chichilnisky, Ed., Markets, Infor-
mation and Uncertainty: Essays in Economic Theory in
B. C. BEAUDREAU
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. ME
278
Honor of Kenneth J. Arrow, Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, 1999.
[27] J. M. Epstein and R. Axtell, “Growing Artificial Societies:
Social Sciences from the Bottom up,” MIT Press, Cam-
bridge, 1996.
[28] M. Chwe, “Communication and Coordination in Social
Networks,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 67, 2000,
pp. 1-16. doi:10.1111/1467-937X.00118
[29] M. Chwe, “Rational Ritual: Culture, Coordination, and
Common Knowledge,” Princeton University Press, Prin-
ceton, 2001.
[30] P. Bolton and M. Dewatripoint, “The Firm as a Commu-
nication Network,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.
109, No. 4, 1994, pp. 809-839. doi:10.2307/2118349
[31] H. Crawford, “Sumer and the Sumerians,” Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, 1991.
[32] L. M. Dudley, “The Word and the Sword How Tech-
niques of Information and Violence Have Shaped Our
World,” Basil Blackwell, Malden, 1991.
[33] L. A. Oppenheim, “Ancient Mesopotamia, Portrait of a
Dead Civilization,” University of Chicago Press, Chicago,
1964.
[34] M. Silver, “Economic Structures of Antiquity,” Green-
wood Press, Westport, 1995.
[35] L. Cavalli-Sforza and F. Cavalli-Sforza, “The Great Hu-
man Diasporas: The History of Diversity and Evolution,”
Addison-Wesley, New York, 1996.
[36] F. Meijer and O. van Nijf, “Trade, Transport and Society
in the Ancient World,” Routledge, London, 1992.
[37] D. Schmandt-Besserat, “An Archaic Recording System
and the Origin of Writing,” Syro-Mesopotamian Studies,
1977, pp. 1-31.
[38] E. Helpman, “General Purpose Technologies and Eco-
nomic Growth,” MIT Press, Cambridge, 1998.
[39] E. Helpman and M. Trajtenberg, “A Time to Sow and a
Time to Reap: Growth Based on General Purpose Tech-
nologies,” National Bureau of Economic Research Work-
ing Paper No. 4854, 1995.
[40] P. Garnsey, K. Hopkins and C. R. Whittaker, “Trade in
the Ancient Economy,” University of California Press,
Berkeley, 1983.
[41] R. Owen, “A New View of Society and Other Writings,”
J. M. Dent and Sons Ltd., London, 1820 (1927).
[42] D. Ricardo, “On the Principles of Political Economy and
Taxation,” John Murray, London, 1817.
[43] J. H. Clapham, “An Economic History of Modern Brit-
ain,” Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1926.
[44] J. A. Schumpeter, “The Theory of Economic Develop-
ment,” Harvard University Press, Cambridge, 1951.
[45] B. C. Beaudreau, “Mass Production: The Stock Market
Crash, and the Great Depression: The Macroeconomics
of Electrification,” Greenwood Press, Westport, 1996.
[46] H. Self and E. M. Watson, “Electricity Supply in Great
Britain,” Allen and Unwin, London, 1952.
[47] D. Acemoglu, S. Johnson and J. A. Robinson, “The Co-
lonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empiri-
cal Investigation,” American Economic Review, Vol. 91,
No. 5, 2001, pp. 1369-1401. doi:10.1257/aer.91.5.1369
[48] D. Acemoglu, S. Johnson and J. Robinson. “The Rise of
Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change, and Eco-
nomic Growth,” American Economic Review, Vol. 95, No.
3, 2005, pp. 546-579. doi:10.1257/0002828054201305
[49] D. Dollar and A. Kraay, “Institutions, Trade and Growth,”
Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 50, No. 1, 2003, pp.
133-162. doi:10.1257/0002828054201305
[50] W. Easterly and R. Levine, “Tropics, Germs, and Crops:
How Endowments Influence Economic Development,”
Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 50, No. 1, 2003, pp.
3-39. doi:10.1016/S0304-3932(02)00200-3
[51] R. E. Hall and C.I. Jones, “Why Do Some Countries Pro-
duce so Much More Output per Worker than Others?”
Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 114, No. 1, 1999,
pp. 83-116. doi:10.1162/003355399555954
[52] D. Rodrik, A. Subramanian and F. Trebbi, “Institutions
Rule: The Primacy of Institutions over Geography and
Integration in Economic Development,” NBER Working
Paper 9305, National Bureau of Economic Research
2002.
[53] M. Alvarez, J. A. Cheibub, F. Limongi and A. Przeworski,
“Democracy and Development: Political Institutions and
Material Well-Being in the World, 1950-1990,” Cam-
bridge University Press, Cambridge, 2000.
[54] R. J. Barro, “Determinants of Democracy,” Journal of
Political Economy, Vol. 107, No. 2, 1999, pp. 158-183.
doi:10.1086/250107
[55] J. B. DeLong and A. Shleifer, “Princes and Merchants:
City Growth before the Industrial Revolution,” Journal of
Law and Economics, Vol. 36, No. 2, 1993, pp. 671-702.
doi:10.1086/467294