Journal of Power and Energy Engineering, 2015, 3, 384-393 Published Online April 2015 in SciRes. http://www.scirp.org/journal/jpee http://dx.doi.org/10.4236/jpee.2015.34052 How to cite this paper: Halperin, J.D. and Tsai, I-T. (2015) Carbon Tax and Renewable Energy Diffusion in the Deregulated Texas Electricity Market: An Agent-Based Analysis. Journal of Power and Energy Engineering, 3, 384-393. http://dx.doi.org/10.4236/jpee.2015.34052 Carbon Tax and Renewable Energy Diffusion in the Deregulated Texas Electricity Market: An Agent-Based Analysis Joshua D. Halperin, I-Tsung Tsai Department of Engineering Systems and Management, Masdar Institute of Science and Technology, Abu Dhabi, United Arab Emirates Email: jhalperin@masdar.ac.ae, itsai@masdar.ac.ae Received February 2015 Abstract In the United States, emission regulations are enacted at a state level; individual states are allowed to define what methods they will use to mitigate their carbon emissions. The consequence of this is especially interesting in the state of Texas where new legislation has created a “deregulated” electricity market in which end-users are capable of choosing their electricity provider and sub- sequently the type of electricity they wish to consume (generated by fossil fuels or renewable sources). In this paper we analyze the effects of carbon tax on the development of renewable gen- eration capacity at the utility level while taking into account expected adoption of rooftop PV sys- tems by individual consumers using agent based modeling techniques. Monte Carlo simulations show carbon abatement trends and proffer updated renewable portfolio standards at various le- vels of likelihood. Keywords Deregulated Electricity Market, Rebewable Adoption, Agent-Based Modeling, Monte Carlo Simulation 1. Introduction Climate change represents one of the largest challenges facing our planet worldwide. Increasing greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions from the combustion of fossil fuels from the electricity sector are one of the major sources of anthropogenic emissions. Effective policies to reduce GHG emissions from the electricity sector are therefore critical in the reduction of emissions. In the state of Texas, electricity services were regulated by the state-run Public Utility Committee of Texas (PUCT) during the 1990s. Each geographical market had only one state-run electricity provider and the rates were set and monitored by PUCT. The electricity provider handled the entire power delivery process: generation, transmission and distribution, and retail sales. The supply of power under such regulatory scheme was reliable but inefficient market wise as there was no choice for the customer under the electricity monopoly [1]. In 1999, the state senate passed Senate Bill 7 (SB7) restructuring the Texas electric industry to allow retail competition
J. D. Halperin, I-T. Tsai by January 2002, paving the way for a deregulated market. Under SB7, all utility companies must dissolve into: 1) The power generation company (PGC): the entity that owns and operates power generation facilities and then sells its electricity into the deregulated market; 2) The transmission and distribution company (TDSP): the entity that owns and operates the wires and power transmission infrastructure; and 3) The retail electric provider (REP): the entity that purchases the power from the PGC and sells it to the end-use customer. They are explicitly forbidden from owning PGCs. These three could remain under the same ownership but the power generation and retail sections must be open to market competition. The electricity demand on the grid is monitored and managed by the Electric Reliability Council of Texas (ERCOT) employing an independent system operator (ISO) to ensure electricity is delivered efficiently/fairly and thereby preventing load imbalances and subsequent swings in spot prices. This organiza- tion also acts as a watchdog over the market prices ensuring fair trade [2]. In portions of Texas that have been deregulated (currently approximately 75% of the state), the PGCs can use any fuel sources (nuclear, coal, natural gas, renewables, etc.) to generate power. Once the power is generated it is sent through power lines that belong to the TDSP. Regardless of the REP chosen by the customer, the trans- mission and distribution is still provided by the local TDSP. As the middle-men between the end-user customers and the PGCs, the REPs purchase wholesale electricity from the PGCs and then offer the electricity to their cus- tomers. They structure deals with the PGC for electricity production with terms unknown to the public. In nego- tiating contractual agreements on the wholesale electricity, the REPs have the ability to buy from providers who supply from different fuel sources including renewable electricity [3]. It is at the REP stage where the market is currently seeing an explosion in the availability of renewable electricity options. The major incentive for the deregulated market is to allow the customers choose their REP as well as sell electricity back to the grid if they opt to do so. When a customer decides on generating and selling their own re- newable power, they may sell their excess power generated to the REP from which they buy electricity, but the REPs are not required to purchase the power. Under SB7, the PUCT continues to oversee the entire electricity market as well as the municipal and cooperative-owned utilities that were not affected by the law. Additionally, SB7 mandates environmental protocols like setting up a renewable portfolio standard (RPS) and mandating that half of all new capacity must be natural gas-fired (as opposed to the more traditional coal) [4]. The RPS mandated that all utilities in the state must produce at least 2,000 MW of renewable energy (solar, wind, biomass, tidal, hydroelectric, geothermal, or landfill gas) by 2009. In 2005, the installed renewable capac- ity was past the 2009 goal and in the State Senate Bill 20 (SB20) an updated goal of 5,880 MW (of which at least 500 must be from non-wind resources) was set for 2015 and a further goal of 10,000 MW was set for 2025 [5]. Meanwhile, the RPS allowed for the creation of a Renewable Energy Credit (REC) trading program that could be used to help meet the renewable energy capacity goals of the RPS. This program, mandated into action until at least 2019, allowed utilities to buy and trade RECs to meet their company’s RE capacity goals if, for whatever reason they did not want to install their own RE capacity directly. The RECs take the burden of power delivery off of the RE buyer and thereby create additional RE demand. For market safety, the entire REC market is monitored and controlled by ERCOT. Penalties for noncompliance with the RPS are overseen and handled by the Public Utility Commission of Texas. If necessary, PUCT can cap the REC price or suspend trading [5]. Once electricity leaves the PGCs and enters the TDSP portion (the grid), it is impossible to distinguish between elec- tricity from different generation sources. For that reason, the RECs permit the tracking of the non-power attributes that renewable energy provides (carbon reduction, sense of environmental protection, etc.). At the end of 2008 the Texas State Energy Conservation Office commissioned the University of Texas at Austin to analyze the performance of the REC trading system. It was concluded that the incredible achievements of the RPS in instigating new capacity created fluctuations in the REC market. The excess renewable energy capacity coupled with the small voluntary market for RECs lead to the collapse of the REC price. Additionally, because of legislative oversight, electricity generation was also outpacing transmission capacity, creating a situ- ation where suppliers could collect funds for generating wind energy without actually being connected to the grid [6]. To move forward effectively, realistic carbon reduction policy has to be identified. This paper thus analyzes the effects of carbon taxes on the installment of renewable capacity in the deregulated Texas electricity market. 2. The Model To analyze the Texas electricity market, we develop a nimble model that combines both an agent-based frame-
J. D. Halperin, I-T. Tsai work which characterizes adoptions of renewable power among individual consumers with a decision tree that characterizes the capacity building and electricity purchasing decisions made by energy consumers. We code the two sub-models on the same program to perform an integrated analysis on the diffusion of power generation profiles and the evolution of electricity Because of the high level of detail in the model, different functions are broken up into both functional groups to simplify calculations and into separate locations for a visually mana- geable and well-defined format. The primary division is by active object class, of which there are five in the model. The first active object class is entitled “Main.” This is where the central calculations of the program take place. The largest and most important is that of pricing the different electricity offerings to the agents. The “Main” class also calculates the carbon abatement from each policy decision and updates the stock of carbon abated accordingly. Lastly, a key function of the “Main” class is writing the simulation results to the correct ex- cel files. The remaining four active classes correspond to the four agents in the model: the power generating company, the industrial sector, the commercial sector, and the residential end-user . 2.1. Consumer According to the Annual Energy Outlook (AEO) 2010, in 2008, residential electricity demand was larger than any of the other sales sectors and made up 111.07 billion kWh out of a total 285.35 billion kWh sold [7]. Utiliz- ing data from the Electric Power Industry Emission Estimates contained within the State Electricity Profile [8 ], the generation of this electricity emitted 79 million metric tons of carbon dioxide in 2008 alone—an amount that is enough to be #11 in the nation behind Alabama—82.9 million metric tons—and in front of Michigan—77.086 metric tons. Under the current market structure in Texas, consumers are able to choose their main electricity source and making their own decisions as to the type and quantity of electricity to buy. Since these purchasing decisions are typically made on a household, we model the residential sector by 1000 representative households to achieve appropriate trade-off between resolution and model speed. Population forecasts were used from the reference scenarios generated at the Texas State Data Center and the model was initialized with 8,322,257 households in 2010, representing roughly 8,322 households per agent [9]. We use total population forecast pro- duced by the University of Texas at San Antonio and assume that the number of households grows at a similar percentage. Since income level affects purchasing decision, we use income distribution data generated from surveys taken between 2005 and 2009 in Texas by the United States Census Bureau to assign income to individual households in the model. In the absence of state-specific data on correlations between electricity usage and income, it is as- sumed that average data for households in the United States is the same for the Texas households. As a result, we use the 2005 EIA Residential Energy Consumption Surveys (RECs) data to delineate the relationship be- tween electricity consumption and household income. Our model also analyze the willingness of a consumer to switch to purchasing renewable energy even if the cost is greater than that of fossil fuel-based electricity. In 2008, the National Renewable Energy Laboratory published the Green Power Marketing Report in which they summarize consumer participation rates in utility green pricing tables [10]. Accordingly, this model utilizes the trend established in the NREL document to characterize the “Green Conscious” population as shown in Figure 1. Since green consumers are defined simply as those willing to pay more for electricity obtained from renewa- ble sources, our analysis assumes that a green consumer is willing to pay up to 15% more for certified renewable energy than for fossil fuels. Figure 1. “Green conscious” consumers by year [10]. 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 20302035 Percentage of "Green Conscious" Population
J. D. Halperin, I-T. Tsai Since not every household in Texas is willing and/or capable to install PV panels on their houses, a willing- ness to build parameter was created and assigned to each consumer. Uniformly distributed among the population (and new agents when they are created from population increases) on the bounds [0, 1] with 0 representing an individual completely unwilling to build PV, the cutoff for actual willingness to build is therefore those house- holds who have a parameter value over a certain threshold value—essentially the percentage of the market in- stalling rooftop photovoltaics. The threshold of willingness to build in the market is set as the business as usual values market penetration values identified by a 2007 NREL report [11] with linear extrapolations up until 2030 (Figure 2). To make these values applicable to this research, it is assumed that the national average of market penetration holds for Texas and that on average all houses have an equal rooftop area. Age nt-based modeling is used to assist in modeling the decision-making aspect in the electricity industry. For the residential sector, a decision tree is devised to analyze household behavior change (Figure 3). Upon entering the statechart, an agent is considered a “PotentialEnergyUser.” These are the customers who can choose their Figure 2. Rooftop PV Market Penetration NREL forecasts extrapolated until 2030 [11]. Figure 3. Consumer decision tree. 0 0.005 0.01 0.015 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035
J. D. Halperin, I-T. Tsai electricity usage makeup—either fossil fuels (FF) or renewable energy (RE)—from their Retail Electricity Pro- vider (REPs). Initially, this decision is made strictly with financial rationale and the willingness to build. If the retail price of FF electricity is greater than that of Re electricity, the agent will purchase renewable power. However, some agents may want to build PV even if the retail RE is more expensive than standard retail elec- tricity. For this reason, a pathway exists for a user to move to build electricity on their property and then pur- chase the remainder of the electricity from FF sources at FF prices. Once agents decide they will buy renewable energy, they must decide whether or not to build PV. If they are willing to buy RE and not willing to build the solar panels or if they simply cannot afford them, they will transition into the “BuysRE” state where they will purchase their electricity directly from the REP. If they choose to build PV, they will build the difference be- tween their budget for electricity and the amount they are currently spending to fulfill their electricity needs (with the cheaper of either RE or FF). It is assumed that all installations take place within a year and therefore the following year the agent will need to purchase less electricity than in the previous year as their PV will be providing some power. To simplify the model, all rooftop PV units are assumed to have a constant efficiency throughout the course of the model. After a consumer decides which type of electricity to purchase, they are either in the state “BuysRE” or “BuysFF.” As is standard in the Texas electricity market, contracts are valid for varying amounts of time but typically lock prices into 6, 12, or 18-month periods. Our analysis assumes every household opts for a 12-month contract, dur- ing which time they are locked into the initial price at the time of contract purchase and after which time they return to being “PotentialEnergyUsers” and can again begin their choice for either RE or FF based on market conditions. 2.2. Industry According to the AEO2010, in 2008 industrial electricity demand was the third largest sales sector in Texas and accounted for 83.06 billion kWh out of a total 285.35 billion kWh sold [7]. Utilizing data from the Electric Power Industry Emission Estimates contained within the State Electricity Profile, the generation of this electric- ity emitted over 60 million metric tons of carbon dioxide into the atmosphere in 2008 alone. Because appropri- ate information to model individual companies is unavailable, the model creates one representative industrial user which represents the collective of industries in Texas. The model uses the industry energy usage forecasts from 2010 through 2030 as provided in the Annual Energy Outloo k [7]. 2.3. Commercial According to the AEO2010, in 2008 commercial electricity demand was the second largest sales sector in Texas and accounted for 91.2 billion kWh out of a total 285.35 billion kWh sold. [7] Again, utilizing data from the Electric Power Industry Emission Estimates contained within the State Electricity Profile, the generation of this electricity emitted over 66.5 million metric tons of carbon dioxide into the atmosphere in 2008 alone. This commercial agent is very similar to the industrial user. Since data is available only at a low resolution, individu- al decision trees are not valid in this iteration of the model. Therefore, the representative commercial entity is assumed to have only a choice between buying RE or FF from the RE power and is motivated primarily by prof- it concerns. The energy needs of the commercial entity are assumed to be consistent with the commercial fore- casts in the reference case of the Annual Energy Outlook [7]. 2.4. REP The Retail Electricity Provider is the intermediary between the power generation and the consumers. In this model, rather than give the REP its own active class division, the actions of the REP are merely simulated in the coding of the “Main” class. It is assumed that all electricity orders are aggregated by the REP and that all delive- ries are made to the consumers without any delay. While this is a somewhat unrealistic, it simplifies calculations and essentially removes the need for day-ahead markets. Based on the sales, the REP sets the retail electricity prices for both fossil fuels and renewable energy with an assumed profit margin added on behalf of the REP. 2.5. PGC The Power Generating Companies (PGC) are the large-scale energy providers who provide electricity by a
J. D. Halperin, I-T. Tsai number of methods. According to the AEO, there are at least 32 broadly-defined generation types including many variations of coal plants, oil/gas facilities, carbonate fuel cells, nuclear and conventional renewable energy facilities. For the purposes of this study, the PGC is viewed as a representative user who provides electricity based on market demand. Since PGCs are the major electricity suppliers in Texas, they are the point source of carbon dioxide emissions in the electricity pathway. All carbon calculations in the model come from the genera- tion at this level and are based upon the information held in the State Electricity Profiles. In 2008, Texas PGCs generated 345,381,850 MWh from non-renewable sources and in the process emitted 252,055,000 metric tons of carbon dioxide [12] for an average of 0.7287 tons CO2/MWh produced. However, the PGCs can also install RE to fill consumer demand. In reality, the gains of wind power in the deregulated Texas market have primarily come from the installation of large scale wind at the PGC level. Primarily, decisions have been based upon re- source availability and profit margins. To simplify our analysis, the PGC is restricted to build only wind or solar power as, historically, these have been the two main beneficiaries of the RPS. An important calculation on capacity is done by the PGC entity in this model. An active event is set to moni- tor total electricity demand from the residential, industrial and commercial sectors monthly. If the current in- stalled capacity is unable to meet the current RE or FF demand, the PGC builds either new RE or FF capacity. We assume any additional fossil fuel capacity built will be natural gas. The decision of what type of capacity to build up depends on both current installed capacity and current building costs. Current installed capacity is taken fro m the AEO’s electric power sector’s forecasts of electricity generating capacity. Beginning with the year 2007, the document outlines the total capacity as well as cumulative planned additions and planned retirements with forecasts up until 2030. This data was therefore used as the baseline capacity in the model. Overall capacity factor was calculated as the total output from the generation facilities (in kWh) divided by total capacity over the course of an entire year (8760 hours) and is 0.582157 for the duration of the simulation. When the electricity demand exceeds the electricity produced by the current generation capacity, the PGC will build new capacity. Since the PGC is also a profit-making entity, they will focus on minimizing potential costs. Therefore, if additional RE capacity is demanded the power entity will compare PV and wind and select the most viable option. In order for the PGC to appropriately evaluate their options, it will need to assess the projected cash flows of each installation over the average life of the equipment. To do so, the program conti- nuously calculates the net present value of an investment of one kilowatt of each renewable energy source. This calculation includes the expected cash flow from each project—both the capital cost and fixed operation and maintenance costs as projected and documented in the Annual Energy Outlook—and a given discount rate. To keep the model widely applicable, the discount rate is established as a parameter that can be set to fit the goals of the user. The model uses the same discount rate as assumed by the Annual Energy Outlook—15%. 3. Results We analyze the installation of RE-based electricity capacity power in the presence of a tax on carbon dioxide emissions. The power generators are treated as the major point source of carbon dioxide emissions and any fines or taxes on carbon output are levied at that level. However, it is assumed that all taxes levied on the PGC entity are fully passed through to the consumers and are reflected in increased electricity prices. Monte Carlo simula- tions are run on multiples of $5 in the range $5 - $25 per metric ton of carbon dioxide emitted, as a proper car- bon tax range suggested by Parry and Pizer [13]. The basic effect of this tax is that it shifts the transition towards cleaner fuels forward as it adds to the cost of the fossil fuels, essentially incentivizing the purchasing of renewa- ble energy. However, this has no effect on the exogenously defined percentage of the population who is instal- ling their own rooftop PV systems and they continue installing PV in accordance with their RE preference. Therefore, the residential RE market continues to grow very similarly to the BAU case for all levels of carbon taxation (Figure 4). In raising the fossil fuel end-use price, the carbon tax makes the usage of RE more finan- cially viable. Therefore, as can be seen in Figure 5, the tax of just $5 per metric ton of carbon emitted actually encourages electricity consumers to begin purchasing RE from the RE power 3 full years earlier than in the base case. In the year 2030, renewable power capacity deviates from the baseline growth again to reach over 90,000,000 kW as the commercial entity switches to renewable energy. As the tax level increases, the time it takes for re- newable energy to reach parity with fossil fuel decreases. As a result of this shift, wind energy is build up in
J. D. Halperin, I-T. Tsai Figure 4. Residential PV projections at varying tax levels. Figure 5. Installed RE capacity for the base case and the case with $5 carbon tax. large quantities to meet the growing demand earlier for each increase in Figure 6 and residential demand shifts fully to RE quicker with each tax raise. The tax shifts demand away from fossil fuel and towards the cheapest alternative and so, with PV being more expensive than the relatively mature technology of wind, the installed PV capacity is unaffected by the varying carbon tax levels (Figure 7). A benefit of the quicker shift away from fossil fuels is that more carbon is abated than in the baseline scenario (Figure 8). The demand for clean energy grows as the carbon tax adds to the cost of fossil fuel energy and wind energy is utilized at earlier years as the carbon tax increases. As this happens, fossil fuel plants are used to meet less demand and emit less carbon overall. The end result is that for each additional dollar of carbon tax, more carbon is abated. This test can also be used to generate an updated renewable portfolio standard for scenarios under various carbon tax regimes. The RPS enumerates installed capacity milestones for renewable energy in Texas. By changing the fossil fuel price, the carbon tax affects the renewable energy technology adoption rate and therefore, if implemented, would lead to different expected values for the installed capacities of renewable energy technology over time. Utilizing the cumulative distribution functions of the probability distributions re- sulting from the Monte Carlo simulations on total installed RE capacity, Table 1 summarizes RPS confidence levels for a carbon tax. First, it can be seen that in the level of the tax affects the speed at which the RE capacity is built up, but that they all induce roughly the same amount of buildup at the end of the 20 year simulation. In- creasing carbon taxes lessen the price difference between FF and RE options earlier and therefore it can be seen that taxes of $ 5 and $ 10 do not have as an immediate effect has higher taxes which encourage buildup starting in 2015. However, as was evident in Figure 6, all taxes lower the price enough to encourage the commercial - 500,000 1,000,000 1,500,000 2,000,000 2,500,000 3,000,000 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022 2024 2026 2028 2030 Residential Installed RE (kW)
J. D. Halperin, I-T. Tsai Figure 6. Installed RE capacity for varying levels of carbon tax. Figure 7. PV installed at varying carbon tax levels. Figure 8. Carbon abated at varying carbon tax levels. 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 PGC-Level PV Capacity (kW)
J. D. Halperin, I-T. Tsai Table 1. Proposed updated RPS under various carbon tax regimes (kW RE installed). Likelihood Level of RPS Target 95% 75% 50% 25% 5% $5 Carbon Tax 2015 9,404,100 9,404,100 9,404,100 9,404,100 9,404,100 2020 41,229,630 41,577,390 41,698,941 41,886,806 42,027,630 2025 42,126,230 42,780,230 43,054,954 43,412,430 43,712,180 2030 91,742,530 92,930,530 93,432,299 94,056,004 94,622,530 $10 Carbon Tax 2015 9,404,100 9,404,100 9,404,100 9,404,100 9,404,100 2020 41,163,330 41,568,992 41,686,366 41,874,035 42,022,759 2025 42,022,630 42,778,630 43,025,218 43,366,630 43,702,630 2030 91,643,830 92,917,287 93,384,134 93,940,163 94,568,750 $15 Carbon Tax 2015 39,725,520 39,863,029 39,928,664 40,005,429 40,078,800 2020 41,171,800 41,506,200 41,677,515 41,875,800 42,031,267 2025 42,076,220 42,687,740 43,014,298 43,409,084 43,723,580 2030 91,763,000 92,791,500 93,383,390 94,043,000 94,601,000 $20 Carbon Tax 2015 39,736,363 39,879,401 39,932,335 40,009,030 40,065,373 2020 41,230,630 41,555,630 41,698,007 41,884,630 42,032,630 2025 42,107,030 42,771,487 43,028,557 43,380,452 43,710,630 2030 91,826,130 92,929,063 93,390,895 94,009,142 94,533,330 $25 Carbon Tax 2015 39,714,730 39,858,730 39,925,411 40,008,597 40,079,530 2020 41,165,650 41,517,430 41,670,504 41,876,530 42,027,871 2025 42,057,330 42,682,930 42,998,018 43,381,330 43,687,238 2030 91,748,430 92,801,763 93,351,871 93,984,620 94,548,430 entity to switch at different times throughout the simulation the end result of which is that by 2030, in each case the installed capacity is increased to meet the substantially increased demand. Since each tax has roughly the same end result, an important policy implication is that if the government is interested in implementing a tax on carbon emitted, the level doesn’t necessarily affect the long-term RE capac- ity in concrete terms but affects the speed at which excess capacity is built up, thereby affecting the carbon ab- atement activity. Therefore, depending upon the goal of the carbon tax (be it to increase RE capacity or to curb carbon emissions), the government can set the taxation level differently. If the goal is abate the most carbon, the government should set a higher tax amount regardless of the political pressure against it. Conversely, if the goal is to simply achieve high RE capacity levels, then it may behoove a legislative authority to take the advice of Parry and Pizer [13] and set the tax so that it simply covers the administrative costs—possibly decreasing the opposition to the tax. 4. Conclusions and Discussions This paper developed a model to analyze the renewable energy potential in the deregulated Texas electricity market when a carbon tax is introduced. Utilizing data on consumer behavior, this research suggests that the combination of agent-based modeling and decision tree analysis can be a very useful tool for analyzing the fu- ture of the deregulated energy market. One problem with the initial goals outlined in the renewable portfolio schedules enumerated in SB7 and SB20 were that they were too conservative. Future iterations of the RPS need to be more liberal and consistent with stated goals. If a given policy instrument will lead to much more installed
J. D. Halperin, I-T. Tsai RE capacity than the published RPS, the state energy legislation will appear ineffectual and will lack credibility in the future. In fact the evaluation of risk is a major factor that will impact the success of renewable energy over the long and short term. If legislators can include in their policies caps which would limit the liabilities of power produc- ers, the producers themselves would be more willing to take risks and install larger amounts of RE. Any sort of legal safety net would undoubtedly add to the costs of RE, but could be justified by the expected increase in RE technological diffusion. Similarly, one way to ensure that policy hedges its risks is by encouraging the diversifi- cation of renewable energy technology. A positive aspect of the SB20 RPS update was that it added an element of variety to the technology of choice (wind) through provisions that 500 MW of capacity be provided by solar energy by 2025. Similar to wind, this target has already been surpassed, but the aim was well-intentioned and just too conservative. References [1] Public Utility Commission of Texas (2011) Power to Choose. Texas Electric Choice Education Program. [2] Calais, C. (2009) Politics 101: What Is Texas Renewable Portfolio Standard? Dallas Examiner. [3] (2010) Public Utility Commission of Texas. Direct Energy Contact US. [4] (2010) Texas Electricity Restructuring Active. U.S. Energy Information Administration. [5] Texas Renewable Portfolio Standard. Texas State Energy Conservation Of fi c e. [6] (2009) Final Report on CM907. Center for Energy Economics: Bureau of Economic Geology, Jackson School of Geo- sciences, the University of Texas at Austin. [7] (2010) Annual Energy Outlook 2010. U.S. DOE, U.S. Energy Information Administration, Washington DC. [8] (2010) State Electricity Profiles—2008. U.S. Energy Information Administration, U.S. DOE, Washington DC, 264- 265. [9] (2008) 2008 Texas Population Projections. Texas State Data Center. [10] Bird, L., Kreycik, C. and Friedman, B. (2008) Green Power Marketing in the United States: A Status Report. 11th Edi- tion, NREL, Golden, 49. [11] Paidipati, J., Frantzis, L., Sawyer, H. and Kurrasch, A. (2008) Rooftop Photovoltaics Market Penetration Scenarios. National Renewable Energy Laboratory (NREL), Golden. http://dx.doi.org/10.2172/924645 [12] (2010) State Electricity Profiles—2008. U.S. DOE, U.S. Energy Information Administration, Washington DC, 264- 265. [13] Parry, I.W.H. and Pizer, W.A. (2007) Combating Global Warming. Regulation, 30.
|