Applied Mathematics
Vol.3 No.12A(2012), Article ID:25995,3 pages DOI:10.4236/am.2012.312A281
General Markowitz Optimization Problems
Department of Mathematical Sciences, University of New Brunswick, Saint John, Canada
Email: stoica@unb.ca
Received October 5, 2012; revised November 5, 2012; accepted November 13, 2012
Keywords: Markowitz Optimization Problems; Coherent Risk Measure; Tail Value at Risk
ABSTRACT
We solve two Markowitz optimization problems for the one-step financial model with a finite number of assets. In our results, the classical (inefficient) constraints are replaced by coherent measures of risk that are continuous from below. The methodology of proof requires optimization techniques based on functional analysis methods. We solve explicitly both problems in the important case of Tail Value at Risk.
1. Introduction
We consider optimal investment for the one-step financial model with a finite number of assets. The classical Markowitz optimization problems are looking for portfolios that either maximize the expected return for a given variance threshold, or minimize the variance for a given expected return. However, using variance as a measure of risk has a serious drawback: high profits are penalized in the same way as high losses. Instead, in what follows we shall use coherent measures of risk (cf. [1]), that provide a much better quantification of risk.
In our set-up, the space of financial positions is a vector space with vector ordering. Besides the origin 0 in E, we distinguish a (strictly positive) reference cash stream denoted by 1. In the space of linear price systems
, i.e., the algebraic dual of
, we fix a total subspace
(i.e., if
for all
, then
) and consider the weak*-topology on
associated to the dual pair
.
A coherent measure of risk (see [2]) is a real valued mapping defined on
which is subadditive:
for
, positive homogeneous:
for
, monotonic:
if
, and translation invariant:
for
and any real
.
The following property will be needed in our results. A coherent measure of risk is called continuous from below (cf. [1,3]) if
for any sequence
in
satisfying
. Note that, if
has a strong order unit, continuity from below is equivalent to the more familiar condition: provided
(see [3,4]).
2. Main Results
Our first result formulates and solves in our set-up the first Markowitz problem, i.e., the so-called “agentindependent optimization problem”: find portfolios that maximize the expected return for a given (measure of) risk. Particular cases have been considered in [5-8].
Theorem 1. Let be an ordered locally convex vector space, and
a total Banach subspace of
. Let
and
be fixed; if
is a coherent measure of risk continuous from below, then the following optimization problem:
(1)
admits optimal solutions.
Proof. According to the structure theorem for coherent measures of risk (see e.g. [3], Theorem 2.1), admits the following representation
(2)
for some weak*-closed convex set, in which all
are positive (i.e.,
for
) and normalized (i.e.,
). Note that continuity from below of
implies continuity in the order convergence topology of all
in formula (2), see [3].
Let us define
where the bar denotes closure. By the continuity from below of and the Krein-Šmulian theorem (see e.g. [9]), the set
is weak*-compact, hence
is compact. Therefore, using (2), the definition of
, continuity from below of
and James’ theorem (see [9]), we obtain for any
:
In particular the sup in (2) is achieved, and for any one has
(3)
where the threshold is given in formula (1).
As for
, from (2) it follows that, for some
, one has
for
. Take
in the latter and, using linearity, obtain
, i.e.,
. Similarly obtain
. This means
, hence the following is well defined:
(4)
Then the max value in (1) equals and is achieved at every
satisfying:
(5)
Indeed, if for some
, take
satisfying
Condition (3) and definition (4) imply that
and the max is achieved at every
satisfying condition (5). □
Problem (1) is for investing a sum of money in securities; it is possible that the investor already possesses a capital with terminal value, in which case minimizing the risk leads to the second Markowitz optimization problem, or “single-agent optimization problem”. Alternatively, one can seek the minimum price which allows us to sell a payment order, and then compile a hedging portfolio of assets such that the risk of the entire operation will be negative or zero. Our second result formulates and solves the second Markowitz problem in our set-up.
Theorem 2. Let be an ordered locally convex vector space, and
a total Banach subspace of
. Let
be fixed; if
is a coherent measure of risk continuous from below, then the following optimization problem
(6)
admits optimal solutions.
Proof. Let us denote
Using a similar argument as in the proof of Theorem 1, we obtain for any:
In particular, for all and any
one has
(7)
As for
, using a similar argument as in the proof of Theorem 1, we obtain that the following is well defined
Then the min value in (6) is given by and is achieved at every
satisfying:
(8)
Indeed, take satisfying
for some
.
Condition (7) and definition (8) imply that
and the min is achieved at every
satisfying condition (9). □
3. Applications
Examples. 1) We can solve explicitly problems (1) and (6) in the important case of Tail VaR (short for Tail Value at Risk). More precisely, consider and define the Tail VaR of order
as the coherent measure of risk with the representation (2) in which
, cf. [1,3,10]. One can easily check that Tail VaR is continuous from below. More, Tail VaR is one of the best coherent risk measures, because is the smallest law invariant coherent risk measure that dominates the Value of Risk (cf. [3,11]). In the context of Theorem 1, we have that
has the optimal solution equal to. Indeed, one can easily check that
and any positive constant multiple of
is an optimal solution of (1). In the context of Theorem 2, we have that
has the optimal solution equal to Tail VaR. Indeed, one can check that
Tail VaR
because
is an optimal solution of (6). This situation occurs in problems (1) and (6) for complete models, such as Black-Scholes and Cox-Ross-Rubinstein.
2) Recall that a coherent measure of risk identifies unacceptable positions, i.e. with strictly positive risk. A good measure of the latter are the so-called relevant measures of risk: given
, a coherent measure of risk
is called g-relevant (cf. [1,3,10]) if
and
imply
.
Let us consider; we have
, the Banach space of bounded finitely additive measures on F and absolutely continuous with respect to P. In this case, all functionals
(given by formula (2) above) describing a coherent measure of risk continuous from below and
-relevant are genuine (i.e.,
-additive) probability measures equivalent to
. The particular case
, i.e., g represents integration with respect to
, has been treated in [2], Theorem 3.4, and the associated optimization problems (1) and (6) have been completely solved in [8,12] (see also [4]).
The research of George Stoica was partially supported by a grant from the Natural Sciences and Engineering Research Council of Canada.
REFERENCES
- P. Artzner, F. Delbaen, J.-M. Eber and D. Heath, “Coherent Measures of Risk,” Mathematical Finance, Vol. 9, No. 3, 1999, pp. 203-228. doi:10.1111/1467-9965.00068
- F. Delbaen, “Coherent Risk Measures on General Probability Spaces,” In: K. Sandmann, et al., Eds., Advances in Finance and Stochastics, Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 2002, pp. 1-37.
- G. Stoica, “Relevant Coherent Measures of Risk,” Journal of Mathematical Economics, Vol. 42, No. 6, 2006, pp. 794-806. doi:10.1016/j.jmateco.2006.03.006
- L. A. Konovalov, “Coherent Risk Measures and a Limit Pass,” Theory of Probability and its Applications, Vol. 54, No. 3, 2010, pp. 403-423. doi:10.1137/S0040585X97984309
- C. Acerbi, “Coherent Representations of Subjective Risk Aversion,” In: G. Szegö, Ed., Risk Measures for the 21st Century, Wiley, New York, 2004, pp. 147-207.
- R. T. Rockafellar and S. Uryasev, “Optimization of Conditional Value-at-Risk,” Journal of Risk, Vol. 2, 2000, pp. 21-41.
- R. T. Rockafellar, S. Uryasev and M. Zabarankin, “Master Funds in Portfolio Analysis with General Deviation Measures,” Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 30, No. 2, 2006, pp. 743-778. doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2005.04.004
- A. S. Cherny, “Equilibrium with Coherent Risk,” Preprint, 2006.
- A. Grothendieck, “Topological Vector Spaces,” Gordon and Breach, Philadelphia, 1992.
- S. Jaschke and U. Küchler, “Coherent Risk Measures and Good-Deal Bounds,” Finance and Stochstics, Vol. 5, No. 2, 2001, pp. 181-200. doi:10.1007/PL00013530
- S. Kusuoka, “On Law Invariant Coherent Risk Measures,” Advances in Mathematical Economics, Vol. 3, 2001, pp. 83-95.
- A. S. Cherny, “Pricing with Coherent Risk,” Theory of Probability and Its Applications, Vol. 52, No. 3, 2008, pp. 389-415. doi:10.1137/S0040585X97983158