Advances in Pure Mathematics
Vol.3 No.9(2013), Article ID:40886,10 pages DOI:10.4236/apm.2013.39097
Global Properties of Evolutional Lotka-Volterra System
1Department of Mathematics, Graduate School of Science, Hiroshima University, Higashi-Hiroshima, Japan
2Research Center for Environmental Risk, National Institute for Environmental Studies, Tsukuba, Japan
Email: yoshinom@hiroshima-u.ac.jp, ytanaka@nies.go.jp
Copyright © 2013 Masafumi Yoshino, Yoshinari Tanaka. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. In accordance of the Creative Commons Attribution License all Copyrights © 2013 are reserved for SCIRP and the owner of the intellectual property Masafumi Yoshino, Yoshinari Tanaka. All Copyright © 2013 are guarded by law and by SCIRP as a guardian.
Received November 9, 2013; revised December 9, 2013; accepted December 15, 2013
Keywords: Lotka-Volterra System; Global Dynamics; Evolution
ABSTRACT
We will study global properties of evolutional Lotka-Volterra system. We assume that the predatory efficiency is a function of a character of species whose evolution obeys a quantitative genetic model. We will show that the structure of a solution is rather different from that of a non-evolutional system. We will analytically show new ecological features of the dynamics.
1. Introduction
In this paper, we study global behavior of an evolutional Lotka-Volterra system for three species
(1.1)
(1.2)
(1.3)
(1.4)
for the unknown quantities and
which are the population of jth species and the mean character value of the second species, respectively. Here
are certain constants, and
and
are death rate of the second and the third species, respectively. The quantities
and
are the predatory efficiency of the second and the third species, respectively. The number
is the mean character value of the second species with minimal cost. The quantity
is the additive genetic variance and
is the cost of evolution, namely, if
decreases, then the cost increases.
The effect of evolution is expressed in terms of (1.4) and the condition that the predatory efficiency is given by
(1.5)
where is a given constant and
is a function of
. An example of a3 is given by (C.1) in Section 3. Equation (1.4) follows the quantitative genetical model (cf. [1-5]. See also Section 7). The evolutional Lotka-Volterra system for two species was studied in [3], where rather detailed numerical analysis was made. As for the system for three species, very little is known as to global behavior of solutions even from a numerical point of view. In this paper, we shall make the analytical study of evolutional Lotka-Volterra model for three species and show several new phenomena caused by evolution.We also refer [6] as to non-evolutional case.
Let Let
and
and
be given. We first prove that (1.1)-(1.4) with the initial condition
(1.6)
have unique smooth time global solution. (cf. Theorem 2). Then, in terms of estimate of a solution obtained in the proof of Theorem 2, we study behaviors of a solution related to evolution. Indeed, we will show that the behavior of a solution near the equilibrium point is different from those in the case of tea-cup attractors for a nonevolutional system. Namely, the decay of the predator starts before the quantity
becomes small because the predatory efficiency a3 tends to zero, by evolution. We remark that although
plays an important role in the non-evolutional system near equilibrium point, the quantity
is crucial in the evolutional one. This is because the quantity
is related with the dynamics of evolution. We remark that the effect of evolution in our system is intermittent in the sense that in some subdomain of the phase space flactuations of pray
occur as in the case of non-evolutional model, while in other subdomain, evolution stabilizes large fluctuations of
and
. We also discuss the role of γ in (C.1), which is related with the sensitivity of evolution to the character bias
. (cf. Lemma 3 and Section 4 for the case of a linear efficiency). In Section 5, we study the uniform convergence of solutions of an evolutional system as the cost of evolution tends to infinity, i.e.,
decreases to zero.
2. Time Global Solution
We shall study the global existence and uniqueness of a solution of the initial value problem. We assume that is the twice continuously differentiable function which satisfies
(2.1)
for some. Moreover we suppose that there exist
and
such that
(2.2)
The following local existence and uniqueness theorem is well known.
THEOREM 2.1. Assume (2.1) and (2.2). Then there exists a such that the system of Equations (1.1)- (1.4) with the initial conditions (1.6) has a unique continuously differentiable solution
,
in
In the following we study the existence of a global solution. We require the condition
(2.3)
Remark. If for some j, then, by the uniqueness, any solution of (1.1)-(1.4) satisfies
. Hence it reduces to a system with less unknown quantities. Note that we avoid this case in (2.3).
We have
THEOREM 2.2. Suppose that (2.3) is satisfied. Then the system of Equations (1.1)-(1.4) with the initial condition (1.6) has a unique global solution in
Proof. First we will show the apriori estimate for all
. Suppose that this is not true. Then, by the continuity of
and
in (2.3) we can take the smallest time
such that
Assume that
If we set
in (1.1)-(1.4), then we have
(2.4)
By the local existence and uniqueness theorem, Equations (2.4) with the initial condition has a unique solution. We denote the solution by
. Then (1.1)-(1.4) with the initial value
at
has a solution
By the uniqueness of the solution we obtain
It follows that
Because
by (2.3), we have a contradiction. Hence we have
By the continuity of
one may assume that
in a sufficiently small neighborhood of
. Then, the second term in the right hand side of (1.1) satisfies
in a sufficiently small neighborhood of
On the other hand, since
can be made arbitrarily small by taking a neighborhood of small, it follows that
there. Hence
is a decreasing function. This contradicts to
Therefore, there is not
such that
which shows the desired estimate.
Next we will estimate N2 from the above. Take that
and add ε times (1.2) to (1.1). Then we have
(2.5)
where
Hence, by setting we obtain
(2.6)
Multiplying to both sides, and integrating from
to
we obtain
(2.7)
By the apriori estimate there exists M > 0 depending only on r, K and such that
Hence we have
Because, we obtain
(2.8)
It follows that, for
(2.9)
Note that the right hand side quantity depends on the initial value and the equation and depends neither on δ > 0 nor on g > 0.
We make the same argument for Take ε so that
and add ε times (1.3) to (1.2). Then we have
(2.10)
where
By setting we obtain the equation
. Because this equation has a similar form as in the case
, we can choose a constant
depending only on
and the initial values so that
Then we argue in the same way and we obtain
(2.11)
In view of the definition of v we have
(2.12)
Next we will estimate from the below. By the estimates of
and
from the above there exists
such that
It follows that
By integrating from to t we obtain
(2.13)
We will estimate N2 from the below. There exist constants depending on the equation and the initial values such that,
Hence we have
By integrating the inequality from to t we obtain
(2.14)
The estimate of from the below can be shown by simple computations.
(2.15)
Next we will prove
(2.16)
Indeed, we have (2.16) for by the initial condition. It follows that if
is sufficiently small, then (2.16) holds true.
In order to prove (2.16) we assume that there exists such that either
or
holds and we show the contradiction. For the sake of simplicity let us assume the former case holds. The latter case can be treated in the same way.By the estimate of
from the above we have, for any
,
there exists a neighborhood V of
such that if
then
and
hold. Hence we have
(2.17)
If then the right hand side of (2.17) is negative. Therefore
is decreasing near
. This implies that
does not tend to
when
. Because
is continuous, we have
. This is a contradiction. Hence we have the desired estimate.
We shall prove the existence of a global solution. Set and let
be the maximal interval for which
and
are defined. If
, then we are done. Assume that
We will show that the limits
and
exist. We set
where
is the right hand sides of the Equations (1.1)-(1.4), respectively. We write (1.1)-(1.4) into an equivalent system of integral equations
(2.18)
By the apriori estimates from the above, is bounded on
. Hence there exists M such that
It follows that the limit
exists. If we define
, then
is continuous up to
. We will show that it is
. For this purpose it is sufficient to show that
We note that
is Lipschitz continuous in each variable because we have apriori estimates of N and
. Namely there exists C > 0 independent of N and
such that
Hence, by (1.1)-(1.4) we have
This proves the assertion. We can similarly prove for .We can solve (1.1)-(1.4) with the initial values
and
at
. Then by the unique existence of the solution we can extend
and
to some neighborhood of
. This contradicts to the definition of
. Hence we have
. This ends the proof.
Remark. 1) We remark that the apriori estimate of a solution does not depend on the cost of evolution and the additive genetic variance g>0. This means that the evolution of a character has little effect to the bound of sum of populations of three species.
2) As a corollary to Theorem 2 we see that if there is no effect of evolution, i.e., then (1.1)- (1.3) with the initial condition (1.6) has a unique global solution. Indeed, (1.1)-(1.4) can be split into (1.1)-(1.4),
The latter equation can be integrated. In view of the uniqueness of the solution of (1.1)-(1.4) we see that (1.1)-(1.3) has a unique solution.
3. Intermittency of Evolution Effect
We shall study the effect of evolution to dynamics of (1.1)-(1.4).More precisely, we will study how the dynamics of (1.4) is related with that of (1.1)-(1.3).By setting we write (1.4) in the form
(3.1)
Let be an integer and
and
be constants. We assume
(C.1)
We also assume that is twice continuously differentiable and nonnegative in the closed intervals
and
. If we denote the right-hand side of (3.1) by
, then, by (C.1) we have
(3.2)
on We define
on
by the right-hand side of (3.2). Define, for
(3.3)
We first study the behavior of.
LEMMA 3.1. 1) Assume Suppose that
. Then
has a unique zero z = 0 in the interval
and
is negative on
.
Assume. Then
has simple zeros,
and 0 on
. The function
is negative on the intervals
and
, while it is positive on
and
. (cf. Figure 1).
Moreover, there exists such that z0 has an asymptotic behavior
(3.4)
when Similarly we have
(3.5)
when
2) Assume If
then
has simple zeros,
and 0 on
.
The function is negative on the intervals
and
while it is positive on
and
. (cf. Figure 1).
If then
has a unique zero z = 0 in
and
is positive on
(cf. Figure 2).
Figure 1..
Proof. We divide the proof into 5 steps.
Step 1. By (C.1) we have
(3.6)
Set
(3.7)
and define
(3.8)
We consider the zeros and the sign of in the interval
Step 2. First we consider the case Assume that
is an odd integer. Because
is an even integer, we have
We have
and
. Because we easily see that
if
, it follows that
has no zero point on
.
In order to study the zero of in (0,1), note
. One easily see that the assumption
is equivalent to
Because
on (0,1], we see that
has only one zero point in the interval (0,1] if
In view of (3.6) we conclude that
has zero points
and 0 in the interval
for some
. It is also clear that if the opposite inequality
holds, then
on
.
Next we consider the case is even. By the same way as in the odd case, we have
,
and
Since
is strictly increasing on (0,1), there exists unique
,
such that
In order to show that
has no zero on
we note
Figure 2. and
Because
and
on
, we see that
has a unique zero point
on
. Clearly,
has only one zero
, because
for all
which proves the assertion. The sign of
is almost clear from the definitions of
and the argument in the above.
Step 3. We will show the asymptotic formula of in (3.4). In view of the argument in Step 2 we may consider
If we set, then we have
(3.9)
where is a polynomial of
with positive coefficients. Hence we have
(3.10)
Hence, for sufficiently small we can uniquely solve (3.10). By an implicit function theorem we see that
is a smooth function of
such that
It follows that
Therefore we have (3.4).
Step 4. Next we will prove (3.5). We will solve namely
(3.11)
for Hence we have
(3.12)
If does not converges to zero when
then there exist c>0 and a sequence
. Since the right-hand side of (3.12) is bounded for
this leads to a contradiction. Hence
is asymptotically equal to
By solving this relation we have
when By (3.11) we have
. It follows that
By simple computations we obtain (3.5).
Step5. If then we have
We can easily see that
on
The solution of
is given by
The rest of the assertion is almost clear from this formula. This completes the proof.
Remark. We will briefly discuss the difference of dynamics of z in (3.1) for f and We note that two functions are identical for
For a small number
, consider the case shown in Figure 2 for
Then f looks like as in Figure 3 where new attractive equilibrium points appear near
because we have made a modification to
so that
The new equilibrium point corresponds to that of
with modulus larger than
. Because of the new equilibrium points we have an apriori estimate of the solution for f. Namely, the orbit started from a neighborhood of the origin does not go beyond
This fact is important since, if otherwise, the efficiency
becomes negative. Note that the dynamics of f and
is the same outside some neighborhood of the boundary
. We also note that a similar situation occurs in the case
with
(cf. Figures 1 and 4).On the other hand, if
, then the dynamics of f and
in
may be different, while in other part both are the same.
We also note that the apriori estimate holds for f. Therefore apart from the neighborhood of the dynamics of f is well approximated by that of
, for which
we can make concrete analysis of the dynamics, although we do not have the apriori estimate.
Figure 3. Picture of f.
Figure 4. Picture of f.
We will study behaviors of solutions under the effect of evolution.
1) Behaviors near the equilibrium point.
We consider how the dynamics of (1.1)-(1.4) is related to the dynamics (1.1)-(1.3) without evolution. We recall that (1.1)-(1.3) without an evolutional effect has what is called a tea-cup attractor. The isocline of (1.1)-(1.3), (3.1) is given by the family of equations
(3.13)
(3.14)
(3.15)
(3.16)
It follows from (3.15) that
(3.17)
One may assume that A is small since is small. By (3.14) we have
(3.18)
Let us first consider the non-evolutional case, z = 0 or the case where evolution becomes stationary, namely. Then there exists C > 0 such that
Hence
is small and
is close to K, by (3.13). It follows that there exists
such that
if
is sufficiently small. In terms of (3.17) and (3.18)
tends to infinity when
. This implies a typical behavior of
and
around an equilibrium point when there is little effect of evolution. Numerical experiments show that the decrease of
occurs soon after the orbit approaches to the equilibrium point, namely
becomes sufficiently large.
Let us consider the evolutional case. Then the main difference from the non-evolutional case is that may tends to zero. For the sake of simplicity, let us consider the case
or
. Assume that there exists an orbit such that
and
grows large. Because
also grows large, it follows from (3.4) that
tends to zero, and we are in the situation that the orbit of
tends to
. Therefore
tends to zero. Hence the boundedness of
implies that
becomes negative. Therefore, by (1.3),
exponentially decreases. Note that the decrease of
begins after
exceeds a certain constant independent of
and
when
. This exhibits a strong contrast to the non evolutional case where the collapse of
occurs after
becomes sufficiently large.
2) Effect of the parameter to evolution.
In the predatory efficiency in (C.1)
represents sensitivity to z. Namely, as
increases,
for small z approaches to a constant function. The dynamics of z is quite different in the cases
and
. Indeed, if
and
then evolution progresses. (cf. Figure 2 and Figure 3). The latter condition means either the cost of evolution is small, or
. We note that the attracttive equilibrium points near
have the effect to hold the orbits around
. Conversely, if
, then we see that fluctuations in progress and rest of evolution takes place.
In the case we have a different situation. Indeed, if
then the evolution becomes stationary. If otherwise, then similar fluctuations in progress and rest of evolution as in the case
takes place. We will show in the next section that in the linear case
we have a sharp contrast to the case
.
3) Fluctuations of and
.
The rhythm of and
is also observed in a nonevolutional system and it is related with the structure of a tea-cup attractor. We have a similar phenomenon for an evolutional system.
Let and
be a solution of (1.1)- (1.4). One can show by Poincaré –Bendixon theorem that
and
are an oscillating solution of two species under appropriate choice of parameters. Note that
tends to zero exponentially. By the continuity of solutions of the initial value problem with respect to an initial value and the apriori estimate of a solution, one can see that for every
and
there exists
such that if
then
for all Here, without loss of generality we may assume that the initial time is 0.Especially, this shows that there appears a rhythm of
and
for some interval of time. Note that
is small and the evolution becomes stationary, i.e.,
.
In order to estimate T, we take,
and
. By integrating the equation of
, one has
Hence, if we have
(3.19)
for sufficiently small, then we have
from which we have the estimate of time length T,
We have a similar condition like (3.19) in the general case
by replacing 0 and T, respectively, by
and
A similar condition like (3.19) holds for some
and T if we have an averaging property:
4) The limit case when evolution cost tends to zero.
We assume. If the evolution cost tends to zero, namely
grows from zero to
, then, by (3.4) and the definition of
approaches to the origin.
Therefore, the evolution progresses, namely z approaches either of the points. It follows that the predatory efficiency
. By the same reasoning as in 1)
tends to zero. We note that in the limit case
the third species dies out. This agrees with an ecological observation.
4. Evolution for a Linear Predatory Efficiency
We will discuss the evolution in the case
(4.1)
where is a real constant and
.As in the previous case we make modifications of
in some small neighborhood of the zero point
such that
.
For the sake of simplicity, we assume that. By repeating the same arguments as in Section 2 we see that the system of Equations (1.1)-(1.4) with the initial condition (1.6) has a unique global solution in
We will study the dynamics of the evolution in relation with the populations and
.We now define
(4.2)
The condition is equivalent to
By definition we may consider (4.3) in the set because, if otherwise,
Set
and calculate the minimum of in I. It is taken at
with the minimum value given by
We recall that is equivalent to
Therefore, if
modulo terms of
namely
(4.4)
then there appear an attractive equilibrium point near the origin
. This means that the predatory efficiency
is close to a constant function if
is sufficiently small. Indeed, the equilibrium point
can be estimated as
In view of the linearity of and the smallness of
near the equilibrium point we see that
is almost constant for small changes of
.
Suppose now that (4.4) does not hold. Then the attracttive equilibrium point near disappears, and there remains an attractive equilibrium point near the zero of
.Hence the evolution progresses and
tends to zero. This alternative between the rest and the progress of evolution shows a high contrast to the case of a convex predatory efficiency function discussed in the previous section.
5. Behaviors of Solutions as Cost Increases
In this section we study the convergence of a solution of an evolutional system to that of a non-evolutional one when the evolutional cost increases, namely decreases to zero. Let
and
be the solution of (1.1)-(1.4). Let
be the solution of the non-evolutional system (1.1)-(1.3), namely
Then we have
THEOREM 5.1. Assume (2.3). Let be arbitrarily given. Then we have
uniformly in t on
Proof. By integrating (1.4) we have
(5.1)
If we make the change of variables, , then we have
(5.2)
where and
Because is uniformly bounded in
by the apriori estimate, it follows that
times the integrand is uniformly bounded in
when
. Hence, the modulus of the integral can be bounded by a constant times
It follows that
uniformly in when
. This entails that
uniformly in
.
For the sake of simplicity we write (1.1)-(1.3) in
where we use the same notation F as in (2.18). Since
we have
(5.3)
where the absolute value of a vector means the norm of a vector. Because we have the uniform estimate of in
by (1) of Remark in Section 2, we have
for some independent of
.
By (1.5) and (5.2) we have
(5.4)
Because there exists a constant
independent of
such that the right hand side of (5.4) can be estimated by
It follows that for any
there exist
and A>0 such that, for
Therefore we have
By Gronwall’s inequality we obtain, for
Because is arbitrary, we have the desired estimate.
6. Discussion
Evolutional Lotka-Volterra system does not seem to be well understood analytically except for the case of two species. In this paper, we have studied how the evolutional change of a character influences global behaviors of a Lotka-Volterra system for three species. We introduced an evolutional equation based on a quantitative genetic model into a Lotka-Volterra system of equations and we proved the existence and the uniqueness of a global solution as well as apriori estimates of a solution. By virtue of these properties, we have given analytical proofs of properties which are different from the nonevolutional system. We hope that some of the properties shown in this paper hold for more general food web settings. It is also interesting to make numerical analysis of our theory in order to understand the effect of evolution. The study of these problems will be left for the future study.
REFERENCES
- R. Lande, “Quantitative Genetic Analysis of Multivariate Evolution Applied to Brain: Body Allometry,” Evolution, Vol. 33, No. 1, 1979, pp. 402-416. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2407630
- R. Lande and S. J. Arnold, “The Measurement of Selection on Correlated Characters,” Evolution, Vol. 37, No. 6, 1983, pp.1210-1226. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2408842
- P. A. Abrams and H. Matsuda, “Prey Adaptation as a Cause of Predator-Prey Cycles,” Evolution, Vol. 51, No. 6, 1997, pp. 1742-1750. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2410997
- P. A. Abrams, “Evolutionay Responses Offoraging-Related traits in Unstable Predator-Prey Systems,” Evolutionary Ecology, Vol. 11, No. 6, 1997, pp. 673-686. http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:1018482218068
- P. A. Abrams and H. Matsuda, “Fitness Minimization and Dynamic Instability as a Consequence of Predator-Prey Coevolution,” Evolutionary Ecology, Vol. 11, No. 1, 1997, pp. 1-20. http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:1018445517101
- Y. Takeuchi, “Global Dynamical Properties of LotkaVolterra Systems,” World Scientific, Singapore, 1996.
- R. A. Fisher, “The Genetical Theory of Natural Selection,” Claredon Press, Oxford, 1930.
Appendix
(A) The following lemma is used in Section 5.
LEMMA. (Gronwall) Let be a closed interval and let
Let u be continuously differentiable in I such that, for some constants
and
the inequality
holds true for. Then we have
on I.
Proof. For the sake of simplicity, we consider the case Denoting the right hand side of the inequality by v(t) we have the relations,
and
Multiplying the last inequality with
, we have
By integration we get
(B) We will briefly show how to deduce (1.4) from the theory of quantitative genetics. Let, g and w be the average character value,the additive genetic variance and the average adaptability of the character value z, respectively. Following the quantitative genetical model we have (cf. [1] and [2]).
The left-hand side is the speed of evolution of a character value. Following Fisher, [7] we have We assume that (cf. [3-5])
where is the cost of evolution. By definition we have
(7.1)
Here,
and
are certain constants. We have
Because one may regards as a constant function when z varies, the right-hand side of (7.1) can be replaced by
Hence we obtain (1.4).