Applied Mathematics, 2011, 2, 556-561
doi:10.4236/am.2011.25073 Published Online May 2011 (http://www.SciRP.org/journal/am)
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. AM
Compactness, Contractibility and Fixed Point Properties of
the Pareto Sets in Multi-Objective Programming
Zdravko Dimitrov Slavov1, Christina Slavova Evans2
1Varna Free University, Varna, Bulgaria
2The George Washington University, Washington DC, USA
E-mail: slavovibz@yahoo.com, evans.christina.s@gmail.com
Received March 6, 2011; revised March 18, 2011; accepted March 22, 2011
Abstract
This paper presents the Pareto solutions in continuous multi-objective mathematical programming. We dis-
cuss the role of some assumptions on the objective functions and feasible domain, the relationship between
them, and compactness, contractibility and fixed point properties of the Pareto sets. The authors have tried to
remove the concavity assumptions on the objective functions which are usually used in multi-objective
maximization problems. The results are based on constructing a retraction from the feasible domain onto the
Pareto-optimal set.
Keywords: Multi-Objective Programming, Pareto-Optimal, Pareto-Front, Compact, Contractible, Fixed Point,
Retraction
1. Introduction
During the last four decades, the topological properties
of the Pareto solutions in multi-objective optimization
problems have attracted much attention from researchers,
see [1-8] for more details. The aim of this paper is to
present some new facts on compactness, contractibility
and fixed point properties of the Pareto-optimal and the
Pareto-front sets, shortly Pareto sets, in a multi-obj ective
maximization problem. The authors have tried to remove
the concavity assumptions of the objective functions
which are usually used in this optimization problem.
The standard form of the multi-objective maximiza-
tion problem is to find a variable

12
,,, m
m
x
xxx R,
1m, so as to maximize
 
12
,,
n
f
xfxfx,fx
subject to
x
X, where the feasible domain
X
is
nonempty,
2, ,
1,
n
J
n
R
is the index set, ,
is a given continuous function for all
.
2n
:
i
fX
n
iJ
Since the objective functions

may conflict
1
n
ii
f
with each other, it is usually difficult to obtain a global
maximum for all objective functions at the same time.
Therefore, the target of the maximization problem is to
achieve a set of solutions that are Pareto-optimal. His-
torically, the first reference to address such situations of
conflicting objectives is usually attributed to Vilfredo
Pareto (1848-1923).
Definition 1. a) A point
x
X is called a
Pareto-optimal solution if and on ly if there does not exist
a point
y
X
such that

i

i
f
yfx for all n
iJ
and
kk
f
yfx for some . The set of
Pareto-optimal solutions of
n
kJ
X
is denoted by
f,XPO and is called a Pareto-optimal set. Its image
,,
f
POPFXf Xf is called a Pareto-front set.
b) A point
x
X
is called a strictly Pareto-optimal
solution if and only if there does not exist a point
y
X
such that
ii
f
yfx for all and
n
iJ
x
y
. The
set of strictly Pareto-optimal solutions of
X
is denoted
by
,X fSPO
and is called a strictly Pareto-optimal
set.
The strictly Pareto-optimal solutions are the multi-
objective analogue of unique optimal solutions in scalar
optimization.
In this paper, let the feasible domain
X
be compact.
It is well-known that and
,POXf
,X fPF are
nonempty,

,,f POX
SPOXf and
,PF X f
f
X [4].
One of the most important problems in multi-criteria
maximization is the investigation of the topological
Z. D. SLAVOV ET AL.557
properties of the Pareto-optimal and Pareto-front sets.
Information about these properties of the Pareto sets is
very important for computational algorithms generating
Pareto solutions [8,9]. Consideration of topological
properties of Pareto solutions sets is started by [5], see
also [4,6,9,10].
We focus our attention on the compactness, contracti-
bility and fixed point properties of the Pareto sets. Com-
pactness of these sets is studied in [4,6,11]. Contracti-
bility of Pareto sets is considered in [12-14]. Fixed point
properties of Pareto-optimal and Pareto-front sets have
been addressed in [7,15].
This paper is organized as follows: In Section 2, we
describe some definitions and notions from topology and
optimization theory. In Section 3, we study compactness,
contractibility and fixed point properties of the
Pareto-optimal and Pareto-front sets.
2. Definitions and Notions
Recall some topological definitions.
Definition 2. a) The set is a retract of
YX
X
if
and only if there exists a continuous function
such that for all
:rX Y

rx x
x
Y
. The function is
called a retraction.
r
b) The set is a deformation retract of
YX
X
if
and only if there exist a retraction and a
homotopy
:rX Y
:0;1
H
XX such that
0
H
x, x
and
 
,1
H
xrx for all
x
X
.
c) The set is contractible (contractible to a point)
if and only if there exists a point such that
Y
aY
a
is a deformation retract of .
Y
Definition 3. The topological space is sa id to have
the fixed point property if and only if every continuous
function from this set into itself has a fixed
point, i.e. there is a point
Y
:hY Y
x
Y such that
x
hx.
Remark 1. Let
X
d Y btwo topological spaces.
A homotopy between two continuous functions
an e
,:
f
gX Y
is defined to be a continuous function
:0;1
H
XY such that

,0
H
xfx and
 
,1
H
xgx
for all
x
X. Note that we can con-
sider the homotopy
H
as a continuously deformation
of
f
to
g
[16].
Remark 2. From a more formal viewpoint, a retrac-
tion is a function such that
r:X Y

rrxrx
for all
x
X, since this equation says exactly that
r
is the identity on its image. Retractions are the topologi-
cal analogs of projection operators in other parts of
mathematics. Clearly, every deformation retract is a re-
Remark 3. It is known that convexity implies contr-
tract, but in genee converse does not hold
ac
tib
rally th[16].
ility, but the converse does not hold in general. Con-
tractibility of sets is preserved under retraction. This
means that if set
X
is contractible and Y is a retract
of
X
, then set Y contractible too.
L us consid a multifunction :Y
is Y
et er
empty, co. Let it be
upper semi-continuous with a nonmpact and
convex image, shortly we say that
is cusco.
Definition 4. The topological space Y is said to h ave
the Kakutani fixed point property if and only if every
cusco :YY
has a fixed point, i.e. there is a point
x
Y
such that
x
x
.
mark 4. A peRe roperty is calld a topological property
if and only if an arbitrary topological space
X
has this
property, then Y has this property too, wre Y is
homeomorphic the
o
X
. Compactness, contractibility and
the fixed point prorties (the fixed point property and
the Kakutani fixed point property) are topological prop-
erties.
Of crse, th
pe
oue topological properties of the Pareto-
op
d the Kakutani fixed
po
timal set relate to the topological properties of the
Pareto-front set, respectively.
Remark 5. The fixed point an
int properties of sets are preserved under retraction
[16]. This means that the following statements are true: if
set
X
has the fixed point property and Y is a retract
of
X
, then set Y has the fixed point pperty too; if
set ro
X
has the Kutani fixed point property and Y is
a retract of ak
X
, then set Y has the Kakutani fixed point
property too
Remark 6.e Ka
.
Thkutani fixed point property is very
cl
et be compact. It can be shown
th
osely related to the fixed point property. If n
SR
has the Kakutani fixed point property, then sin
continuous functio n from S into itself can be viewed as
a cusco it follows that seS will also have the fixed
point property.
Remark 7. Ln
SR
ce any
t
the Kaat set S havingkutani fixed point property is
equivalent to S having the fixed point property. Re-
mark 6 has shown that if S has the Kakutani fixed
point property, then S hashe fixed point property.
Now, let :SS t
be cusco, S have the fixed point
property a
,
g
ph S
rem it follows that there is an appro
xyS |yx

. From
nd
Cellina’s Theoximate
continuous selection h of
[17,18]. That is, for each
kN
there exists acontius function :
k
hS S


nuo
such that

1
,,gph
for
k
dxh k
xall
x
S
.
rop-From the assxed point p
erty, it follows that each function k
h has a fixed point
k
ump has the fition thatS
x
S
. As a result we get a sequenc
e
1
kk
x
S
such
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. AM
Z. D. SLAVOV ET AL.
558
that


1
,,xxgph
, i.e. th
kk
dke point
,
kk
x
x
approaches the set

gph
. The set S is c
implying that there a convergensubsequence



1
1k
mk k
xx
such that

0
lim mk
k
ompact,
exists t

mk
x
xS
 
. We
also see that
 




1
,,
mk mk
x

dxgph mk
. But
is cusco, then gph


mk

00
,xx
is closed. Taking the lim
g
it as
k we have and obtain
 

,
k mk
x ph

lim m
kx

0
 . This means that
x
S is a fixed point for
, see also [19]. Finally, we
t S has the Kakutanf ixed point property.
We usm
R and n
R as generic finite-dimensa
ves. Ition
find tha
e
i
ionl
ctor spacen addi, we also introduce the follow-
ing notations: for every two vectors ,n
x
yR,
12
,, n
xxx,x

12
,,,
n
y
yy y mi
eans i
x
y
for
all n
iJ,

12
,,, 12
,, ,
nn
x
xxx yyy
eans
i
y m
i
x
y for iJ
1
,
all order),
 
2 2
,, ,,,
nn
n (wea
1
kly componentwise
x
xxyxyy
means ii
y
x
y for all
rder), and
n
iJ (strictly com
1
,
ponentwise o

2 12
,, ,,,
nn
x
xxx yyyy means ii
x
y for all
n
iJ and kk
x
y
order)
n Result
for some n
J (comentwise
.
3. ai
k
transfer our
pon
M
s usual, the key idea is toAmulti-objective
optimization problem to mono-objective optimization
problem by defining a unique objective function.
We begin with the following definition: define a mul-
tifunction :
X
X
by

x
yX|fyfx

for all
x
X; define a function :
s
XR by
s
x

j
1
n
j
f
x f
or all
x
X.
Choose
x
X and consider an optimization problem
wile objth a singective function as follows: maximize

s
y subject to

y
x
. By letting
x
vary over all
of
X
we can identify different Pareto-optimal solutions.
This optimization technique will allow us to find the
whole Pareto-optimal set.
In this paper, we will discuss the role of the following
assumptions:
Assumption 1.
X
is a nonempty, compact and con-
vex set.
Assumption


2. Arg max,1sx
for all
x
X
.
Assumption 3 If
0
ii
.is a metric in , d m
R
x
X
, then


0
k
x
0,
lim dy
k
for
0
li ,dx xm 0
k
k
and
all
00
y
x
.
Assumption 4.
f
is to obtain a set
ie.
ur aimof conditions which guaran-
point
pr
s bijectiv
O
tee the compactness, contractibility and fixed
operties of the Pareto sets.
Remark 8. Let
Cl X be the set of all nonempty
compact subsets of
X
. A sequence of sets

A
1
kk
X is said to Wn converge to Cl ijsma
A
Cl X if
and only if for each
x
X
,

lim ,dxA . ,
kdxA
k
o Assumption 3.
These definitions and ptions allow us t
the main theorem of this p
Theorem 1.
See alsassumto presen
aper.
If Assumptions 1, 2, 3 and 4 hold, then:
a)
,,POXfSPOXf.
b)
,POXf and
,PFXf are compact.
c)
,POXf and
,PFXf are contractible.
d)
,POXf and
,PFXf have the fixed point
properties.
rder to givoof of Th
sommas.
In oe the preorem 1, we will prove
me le
Lemma 1. If
x
X
,

,
x
PO Xf is equivalent to
x
x
.
Proof. Let
,
x
PO Xf e that and assum
x
x
. From
x
x
the conditions and
x
x
, there exists it follows that
\
y
xx
such that
f
yfx. As a result we get that
s
ysx, but
,
x
PO Xf implies
s
ysx
and
f
y by assumption fx. Since
f
is bijective,
we deduce
x
y
; which contradicts the condition
\
y
xx
us, we obta i n
 
. Th
x
x
.
Conversely, let
x
x
and assume that
,
x
PO Xf. From the assump
,
x
PX fOtion , it
follows that the

re exists
y
X\ x such that
f
yfx. Thus we deduce that

y
x
and
x
y
,
which contradicts the condition
 
x
x
. Therefore,
we obtain
,
x
PO Xf.
The lemma is proven.
Lemma 2. If
x
X
, then

Arg max,sx
,POXf.
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. AM
Z. D. SLAVOV ET AL.559
x and as-
sum
Proof. Let us choose


Arg max,ys
e that
,
y
PO Xf

,
. From the assumption
y
PO Xf it follows that there exists
\zX y
such that
 
f
zfy derive

zx
and
. As a result we

s
z
fore,
sy. This leads to a con
we obtain

,
tradic-
tion; there
y
PO Xf.
The lemma is
sing
proven.
Now, u

Ar ,
g max,
s
xPOXf
(Lemma 2) and


Arg max,1sx
n to constru
(Assumption 3),
wct a function e are in a positio
,r:XPO Xf such that
rxArg max


,
s
x
for all
x
X, see also Defi-
nition 1 and Lemma 1.
ying Lemma
Remark 9. Appls 1 and 2 it follows that:
if

,
x
PO Xf, then
x
rx; if
,
x
X\POXf
then

,
x
rx. This me
 
ans that ,POXf. rX
Lemma 3.
is continuous on
X
.
Proof. at if First, we will prove th

1
kk
x
X
such that
and
nces

yX
are a pair of seque
1
kk
lim k
k0
x
xX and

kk
y
x
fr allo, then kN
f

1
y
there exists a convergent subsequence okk
whose
to

0
limit belongs
x
.
ion The assumpt
kk
y
x
for all kimplies

N

kk
f
yfx for all kN. From ondition

k
yX
it
the c
exists a convergent
q
1k
bsequence

11
follows that ther

kk
su
e
su kk
qy


ch thatlim k
k 0
yX
.
e exists nvergent subsequence
k
such that

kk
qp
and 0
lim k
px
Therefore, th

k
p
er
11kk
x

a co
k
.
Thus, we find that
kk
f
qfp
for a
the limit as k we obtain
 
00
ll kN. Taking
f
yfx. This
implie s
00
y
x.
This means that
is upper seuous mi-continon
X
[20].
Secon prd, we willove that if

1
kk
x
X
is a se-
qutoence convergent 0
x
X and

00
y
x
, th
there
en
exists a sequethat nce

1k
yX
suc
kh

kk
y
x
for all kN and lim
k
As usual, the distanceen theX
0k
yy.
e betw point0
y
and
the set
k
x
X
is denoted by
0,syx|x.in
kk
d x
fdi Clearly,
k
x
is
nonempty and compact; therefore, if
0k
y
x, t
hen
there exists
k
ˆ
y
x such that dd
o cases as

0
,
yy
. Th
kˆ
ere
are tw follows: if 0

k
y
x
, the0n k
d
and let 0k
yy
; if
0k
y
x
, thennd let
kˆ
yy
k
d0 a
. Thua sequence s, we get

1
kk
d
R
and a
sequence

1
kk
yX
such that
kk
y
x
f
kN
or all
and
0,k
y. Ass
lim k
k
k
ddyumption
0
3 and
x
x

imply that the sequence
gent and

1
kk
d
is conver-
lim 0
k
kd

. Finally, we obta0
yin lim
k k
y
.
s meansThi that
is los onwer semi-continuou
X
[20].
In summary,
is continuous on
X
.
eo -
, n-
The lemen. ma is prov
h
, a
Lemma 4 [21, Trem 9.14 – The Maximum Theo
rem]. Let n
SRm
R, :hSR a co
tinuous functionnd :DS
be co
unction. Th,
a mp
enth act-valued
ane function d continuous multif
:Rh*
defined by is continuous on , and the
multifunction D*:S
ine defd by

D*x D|h ,x h*
 
 is compact-valu-
ed and upper semi-co ntinuous on .
. r is continuous on
Lemma 5
X
.
Proof. As was mentioned before, the multifunction
is com and continuous pact-valuedon
X
. Applying
Lemma 6 for SX
 and D
, we deduce that
r
is an uppe semi-continuous mltirufon onuncti
X
.
isObviously, an upper semi-continuous multifunction
continuous when viewed as a function. Th shows that is
r
is continuous on
X
.
The lemma is proven.
Lemma 6 [2 1, Theorem 9.31 – Schauder’s Fixed Point
Theorem]. Let :hS S be a continuous function from
anonempty, compactd convex set n
SR into itself,
th
be
an. en h has a fixed point
Lemma 7 [21, Theorem 9.26 - Kakutani’s Fixed Point
Theorem]. Let SR a nonempty, compact and
convex set and the multifunction :S
n
S
usco,
then
be c
ha fixed point. s a
Lemma 8.
,POXf is homeomorphic to
,PF X f.
Proof. It is well-known th
a compact. In fact, the
at every continuous image of
pset act set is com
X
is compact
and th is continuous one function r
X
. Hence, the set
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. AM
Z. D. SLAVOV ET AL.
560
,X frmpact. Recalling that POX
tion :n
is cothe func-
f
XR
is
str
continuous, we deduce that the re-
iction

:, ,hPOXf PFXf of
f
is con-
tinuous too. We know that the function h is bijective.
Consider the ine function

,POXf of h. As we proved
abov

,OXf is compact; therefore, 1
h
vers

1:,hPFXf
e, the set P
is
continuous tod that function
h is homeomorphism.
The lemma is proven. ing Lma 1 we get that

,,PO XfS.
From Lemma 5 it follows that there exists a continu-
ous function

:,rXPOXf such that
o [22]
Proof of Theorem
PO
. As a result we fin
1. Apply em

X f
the
rX

,X f and

ArrxPO


g maxs, x
for all
x
X. This means that
,OXf Pis a retract of
X
.
We know that
X
is nonempty, compact and convex
(Assumption 1), i.e. it is contractile, has the fixed point
and the Kakutanerties, see Lem
b
xed point prop
allows us to deduce
i fi
and 7. Thisk mas
6
remart tha
,X f
d the
nvex in
ractibility
x.
se th
nctions which
PO
pact and contractib fixed point an
ni fixed point prop
[6
is com
Kakuta
ge emark 11.
the
ve
do
concavity assump
le, has the
erties.
sets
ge
, compactness a
ain is comp
are that the proo
tions on the objective
Vol
According to Lemma 8 we obtain that the Pareto-front
set

,PFXf is compact and contractible, has the
fixed point and the Kakutani fi xed point pr op e rties too.
The theorem is proven.
Remark 10. It is important to note that the
Pareto-optimal and Pareto-front are
n
act and The
f t ue
ship between the first two.
iza-
tion,” Springer, Berlin, 2003.
r Optimization: Theory, Applications, and
inger, Berlin, 2004.
ican Mathematical Society,
onvex Optimization,”
ptimization with Quasi-Concave Functions,”
: The-
n
d c
di
fu
ot co
neral, it is not difficult to
ont
conve
d no
[9]
neral.
RAs we have shown in Lemma 6, if an ar-
bitrary set is nonempty, compact and convex, then it has Ca
fixed point property. In
rify that the Pareto-optimal and Pareto-front sets are
nonconvex, but they are compact and contractible. Thus
among noonvex setsnc
not have direct relationship with the fixed point prop-
erty. There are examples of compact and contractible sets
which do not have the fixed point property. It is not
known what types on nonconvex sets have this property.
4. Conclusions
We have shown the compactness, contractibility and
fixed point properties of the Pareto-optimal and Pareto-
front sets in multi-objective mathematical programming
when the feasible dom
two important facts
Conc
are usually used in this optimization problem, and that
the Pareto-optimal and Pareto-front sets are not compact
and convex in general.
The authors see three directions for future r esearch re-
lated to this article: one would look for general condi-
tions on the objective functions without the assumption
of their concavity; one would analyze specific types of
concave or quasi-concave objective functions; and one
would study the relation
5. References
[1] J. Cohon, “Multi-Objective Programming and Planning,”
Academic Press, Cambridge, 1978.
[2] Y. Collette and P. Siarry, “Multi-Objective Optim
[3] J. Jahn, “Vecto
Extensions,” Spr
[4] D. Luc, “Theory of Vector Optimization,” Springer, Ber-
lin, 1989.
[5] B. Peleg, “Topological Properties of the Efficient Point
Set,” Proceedings of the Amer
Vol. 35, No. 2, 1972, pp. 531-536.
doi:10.1090/S0002-9939-1972-0303916-2
] Z. Slavov and C. Evans, “On the Structure of the Effi-
cient Set,” Mathematics and Education in Mathematics,
. 33, 2004, pp. 247-250.
[7] Z. Slavov, “The Fixed Point Property in Convex Multi-
Objective Optimization Problem,” Acta Universitatis Apu-
lensis, Vol. 15, 2008, pp. 405-414.
[8] R. Steuer, “Multiple Criteria Optimization: Theory, Com-
putation and Application,” John Wiley and Sons, Hobo-
ken, 1986.
M. Ehrgott, “Multi-Criteria Optimization,” Springer, Berlin,
2005.
[10] S. Boyd and L. Vandenberghe, “C
mbridge University Press, Cambridge, 2004.
[11] Z. Slavov, “Compactness of the Pareto Sets in Multi-
Objective O
Mathematics and Education in Mathematics, Vol. 35,
2006, pp. 298-301.
[12] J. Benoist, “Contractibility of the Efficient Set in Strictly
Quasi-Concave Vector Maximization,” Journal of Opti-
mization Theory and Applications, Vol. 110, No. 2, 2001,
pp. 325-336. doi:10.1023/A:1017527329601
[13] N. Huy and N. Yen, “Contractibility of the Solution Sets
in Strictly Quasi-Concave Vector Maximization on Non-
compact Domains,” Journal of Optimization Theory and
Applications, Vol. 124, No. 3, 2005, pp. 615-635.
doi:10.1007/s10957-004-1177-9
[14] Z. Slavov, “Contractibility of Pareto Solutions Sets in
ave Vector Maximization,” Mathematics and Edu-
cation in Mathematics, Vol. 36, 2007, pp. 299-304.
[15] Z. Slavov, “On the Engineering Multi-Objective Maxi-
mization and Properties of the Pareto-Optimal Set,” In-
ternational e-Journal of Engineering Mathematics
ory and Application, Vol. 7, 2009, pp. 32-46.
[16] A. Hatcher, “Algebraic Topology,” Cambridge Univer-
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. AM
Z. D. SLAVOV ET AL.
Copyright © 2011 SciRes. AM
561
nlin-
erie O
ematical Economics: Lin-
ourse in Optimization Theory,”
Publica-
sity Press, Cambridge, 2002.
[17] J. Borwein and A. Lewis, “Convex Analysis and No
ear Optimization: Theory and Examples,” Springer, Ber-
lin, 2000.
[18] A. Cellina, “Fixed Point of Noncontinuous Mapping,”
Atti della Accademia Nazionale dei Lincei Sttava Cambridge University Press, London, 1996.
[22] A. Wilansky, “Topology for Analysis,” Dover
Rendiconti, Vol. 49, 1970, pp. 30-33.
[19] J. Franklin, “Methods of Math
ear and Nonlinear Programming, Fixed Point Theorems,”
Springer, Berlin, 1980.
[20] A. Mukherjea and K. Pothoven, “Real and Functional
Analysis,” Plenum Press, New York, 1978.
[21] R. Sundaran, “A First C
tions, New York, 1998.