Modern Economy
Vol.06 No.01(2015), Article ID:53082,20 pages
10.4236/me.2015.61004

Analyzing Capitalism

Mahkame Megan Khoshyaran

Economics Traffic Clinic (ETC), Paris, France

Email: megan.khoshyaran@wanadoo.fr

Copyright © 2015 by author and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution International License (CC BY).

http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/

Received 21 November 2014; revised 10 December 2014; accepted 17 December 2014

ABSTRACT

The intent of this paper is to show that for the capitalist system to survive some specific form of economic activities have to be practiced. These economic activities are introduced in this paper in the form of economic theorems. Their existence and credibility are exhibited through structured proofs. Six economic theorems are introduced in total. In theorem 1 it is stated that for a capitalistic system to survive the domestic and international market share of territorial manufacturing and businesses should be kept limited. In theorem 2, it is stated that both manufacturing and businesses should have a limited life span. In theorem 3, it is stated that growth should be based on production and creation of real values. In theorem 4, it is stated that the relationship between (manufacturing, businesses) and banks should be based on wealth collected out of production activities and creation of real values in manufacturing and services. In theorem 5, it is stated that monopolistic and oligopolistic based economic activities are in conflict with small manufacturing and service activities. In theorem 6, it is stated that the capitalist system should evolve into a Parallel-Multi-Layer Capitalism (PMLC) where small and large economic activities can work on parallel levels with no interference.

Keywords:

Small Business, Limited Life Span, Oligopoly, Monopoly, Banking System, Parallel Multi-Layer Captalism

1. Introduction

The stock market collapsed in September 2008, [1] . As the economic lives of people changed, many questioned the effectiveness of remedies that were applied around the world like injection of millions of currencies in financial markets, regulations, or nationalization schemes. The collapse of the stock market unraveled a fundamental structural fault in capitalism. A panoramic look at the capitalistic system reveals two important economic structures: 1) an expanded system of monopolies and oligopolies; 2) stock market and large banks. The collapse of the stock market shows that the 2 structures are in conflict with the fundamental idea of capitalism which is the existence and operation of small manufacturing and business firms. Many small size manufacturing firms and businesses have been forced out of the market because they could not compete with oligopolies. Oligopolies take an ever larger share of both internal and external markets. Oligopolies accumulate technological capital and reduce human capital. Oligopolies have easier access to bank credit and comprise a large percentage of the stock market assets.

Many economic doctrines agree with this assessment. In the “neo-Marxist” theory of Wallerstein, [2] [3] , the main problem with the capitalistic system is identified to be polarized in centre by a dominant monopolistic structure, and small business structures in the periphery as independent entities, and as symbiotic structures in the semi peripheral region. Some researchers identify capitalism as a function of four elements: credit which is related to the banking system, commodification which is related to the scale of production, creativity (and innovation) which relates to labor force as a whole, and competition which relates to competition among various economic structures for ever larger profit, [4] . In his theory of general equilibrium, [5] [6] identify price as the only element that explains the behavior of supply and demand in an economy with a set of interacting markets. In his opinion, there exists a set of prices that results in a general equilibrium. Market equilibrium can only be reached if and only if there are several or many interacting markets, and the entry into the interacting markets is free. Walras did not consider that an economic structure based on monopolies or oligopolies can reach market equilibrium. Many Keynesian and post-Keynesian economists, [7] [8] criticize the general equilibrium theory for exactly the same reason that economic market is skewed due to the existence of large scale economies, and market reaction is time dependent, in other words, Keynes implied that demand and supply are functions of time and not static entities. Therefore in contrast to Say’s law, [9] aggregates production or supply does not necessarily create an equal quantity of aggregate demand at a certain time point. Ricardo, [10] , in his law of diminishing return, states that if more units are added to one of the factors of production and the rest is kept constant, the output created by the extra units gets smaller to a point where overall output begins to fall. This does not apply to the technology-labor combination, the more technology incorporated in production while labor is either kept constant or reduced, the more the overall output. This way labor becomes redundant. One of the main characteristics of monopolies or oligopolies is the overturn of the law of diminishing returns.

The ever market share expansion and capital intense operation of monopolies and oligopolies requires a financial structure that could support it. This financial structure was the stock market. In a span of a short period, the stock market facilitated the exit of small manufacturing and businesses and paved the way for large scale economies. The stock market has succeeded in redesigning demand in favor of large capital investment. In the stock market based economy growth is a redefinition of real growth. The stock market has redefined economic growth. Economic growth is a function of the production and distribution of financial products. This leads to an ever expansion of capital, larger and larger markets for large economic operations, and an upward evolution of a network of ventures that support large manufacturing and business operations. Like any economic operation, the stock market has induced its own demand. The stock market based demand, is the demand for stock market products. Economic growth is measured by the increase in demand for stock market products. The consequence of the shift from real demand to stock market demand is an economic slowdown. Instability is inherent in the structure of the stock market. [11] . Forces that act on each other in the stock market create bubbles and collapses.

To help large scale economies, the stock market, created a sub system, in the form of large banks. These banks are specialized in processing and developing financial products. The conventional banking system has completely collapsed. In its’ place banks look for ever larger liquidity base through means provided by the stock market, rather than conventional means of individual saving deposits, and business and manufacturing surplus deposits, [12] . The main advantages of relying on stock market financial products to fill up the liquidity base is that banks do not have to worry about economic activities and needs for investment and lending complications. This policy has brought about a slowdown of savings and business surplus deposits, [13] .

Small manufacturing and business firms are fragile. They cannot fend off stock markets’ acute fluctuations in stock prices and banking practices modeled to fit the needs of oligopolies. The capitalistic system defined by a network of oligopolies and their tentacles (subcontractor firms) is extremely volatile since it has to rely on the stock market and large banks. Many bank regulatory measures which have been in place for a long time failed to protect banks all in search of ever expanding markets. The main body that regulated the banks is the central bank that dictates interest rates, minimum allowable deposit level, exchange rates, and minimum and maximum level of credit granted. In fact the politics of the central bank has enforced the stock market economic strategies. No radical reforms in financial regulations can clamp down the risks associated with the stock market practices. Fundamentally, the system is designed to dominate an ever increasing market shares that benefit few large businesses [14] . The economic size of oligopolies on theory can protect them from random ups and downs of capital investment by absorbing shocks. This would not be the case for small firms. Their survival wholly depends on the production of real economic values. These firms usually have a limited investment capital, and surplus fluctuates in response to demand. In another word, the survival of small firms depends on the real economic growth, and what used to be called capitalism.

Given the unstable nature of the oligopolistic based capitalism, it seems logical to separate the small scale economy from the large scale economy. A necessary condition for separation is to limit the market share of small scale firms. The limited market shares in the small scale economy are the fundamental concept behind the concept of Parallel Multi-Layer Capitalism (PMLC) system proposed in this paper. PMLC consists of two layers of economic activities and many supporting sub-layers. The two major parallel layers in the PMLC system are the small scale economic activity layer and the large scale economic activities layer. These two layers are completely separate from each other with no overlaps. Each major layer has its supporting layers. These support layers help each system of economic activity to function efficiently. An example of a support layer is a banking system adapted to the characteristics of the corresponding major layer.

The PMLC system is based on six theorems. The intent of these theorems is to assure the existence and the continuity of the small scale economic activities. Analysis of the large scale economic activities is not the subject of this paper. The theorems introduced are solely applied to small scale economies. In Theorem 1, it is stated that the survival of the small scale system depends on limiting the market share of manufacturing and businesses. In Theorem 2, it is stated that small manufacturing and businesses should have a limited life span. The life of an economic activity is determined by market trends, usefulness of the product or service (demand), and technical advancements. Each economic activity should persistently prepare for the next generation of activities borne out of the present ones. In Theorem 3, it is stated that growth should be based on production and creation of real values. In Theorem 4, it is stated that the relationship between (manufacturing, businesses) and banks should be based on financial transactions resulting from production activities and creation of real values. In Theorem 5, it is stated that large scale economies (oligopolies) are in conflict with small scale economies (small firms). Oligopolies distort the economy both by their scale of activities and their relationship with banks. Where due to economies of scale a monopoly or oligopoly market form is required, it should be kept separated from the real economy. In Theorem 6, it is stated that large scale operations should produce goods that are distinctly different from small scale operations, and should operate in completely separated markets in order to eliminate competition over market shares.

2. Fundamentals of New Capital

Small scale economies suffer from two mechanisms that pull the system apart. These mechanisms are identified as: 1) large scale production operations (monopolies, or oligopolies), [15] - [22] and 2) financial markets (stock markets, and large banks). The impact of (1) is the profound change in the production techniques. Technology has replaced labor for most parts. Technologies have paved the way for mass production of goods and services, and thus have altered the nature of labor. By itself, labor has no inherent value. Machines are doing the thinking and the innovation. As technology replaces labor, labor becomes more and more ineffective and thus makes up a smaller percentage of capital assets. The impact of (2) has changed the role of money. It has caused mutation in a way that allows money to be created and distributed absolutely independent of production of real values. Production has become a function of monetary manipulations. The natural evolution of the free market necessitates developing healthy building blocks.

The building blocks are defined as: 1) the free market economy should be based on free entry and exit of small manufacturing and business activities. 2) The free market should be a collection of production and services that create real economic values. Real economic values refer to those products and services that help improve human economic conditions, general well being and advancement. Examples of real valued products are, electricity, and electrical based products, laser based products, optics, etc. Examples of real value producing services are: health care services, educational services, construction services, etc. 3) Small scale businesses should have limited market shares. Each economic activity will procure a time-fixed percentage of the market share. Time fixed refers to a fixed percentage over time. 4) The free market economic system should create and encourage an intelligent labor force. Intelligent labor is a multi-skilled force capable of independent thinking and innovation. 5) The free market economic system should be based on a dynamic agent-based growth. A dynamic agent-based growth is each individual’s capacity to produce real values. A macroscopic growth is the sum of individual dynamic agent-based growth. A dynamic growth is based on eliminating surplus as a function of increasing market share and rise in unit prices, [23] . Dynamic growth is based on eliminating diminishing returns. All the above factors can be represented by the flow and the density of supply and demand. The flow and the density of demand represent endogenous adaptation of economic agents. The flow and the density of supply represent labor-technology interaction and the diminishing returns. 6) In a free market economy, economic activities1 should have a limited life span. Each economic activity should last as long as it produces real values. This is a response to flow and density of real demand that diminish in time. During the useful life of an economic activity, labor-machine productivity should stay positive but bounded. This implies that the flow and the density of supply are finite over time and should respond to real demand. The flow and the density of supply is a measure of labor-machine productivity. 7) A productive free market economy is an environment that allows for new activities that are created as a result of innovation from within the economic activities (innovation due to intelligent labor force) or from outside (individuals (consumer innovations)). 8) For the market to function efficiently it is necessary to separate small scale economy and large scale economy. Small scale economy refers to a system of small manufacturing and business. Large scale economy refers to a system of monopolies and oligopolies. It is assumed that oligopolies have large market shares that get larger in time. Whereas, small scale economies have fix market shares over time. 9) Each scale of economic activity makes up the two major layers, each major layer has many sub-layers, the function of which is to support and help more efficient functioning of each major layer. The support sub-layers are mainly banks. A system of small size banks sees to the investment needs of small scale economic activities. A system of large size banks sees to the investment needs of large scale economic activities. The two banking systems function in parallel. Figure 1, demonstrates the relationship between small scale economic activities and their corresponding banking system. As is shown by arrows, small scale businesses interact with each other through a supply chain, and capital lending, while they interact with banks through a system of lending/borrowing activities, where small businesses borrow limited capital with interest rates functions of the risk levels, and the amount of capital borrowed, [24] .

1Here economic activity refers to small scale businesses. If an economic activity is a monopoly or an oligopoly it is stated as such.

Figure 2 demonstrates the relationship between oligopolies and large banks. As is shown by arrows, oligopolies do not interact with each other through a supply chain, and capital lending, but they interact with banks through a system of lending/borrowing activities, where they borrow unlimited capital with low interest rates.

Figure 1. Small scale activities economy.

Figure 2. Monopolistic and oligopolistic economy.

An empirical data from the bank of England shows that the three-month annualized rate of growth of lending to large businesses picked up in the three months to May in 2014. The annual rate of growth of lending to both small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) remained negative, as is demonstrated in Figure 3 [24] . This could be explained by the lack of separation by size of the banking system.

3. Fundamental Theorems and Proofs

Three fundamental elements are identified from the literature in the theory of capitalism. These elements are: 1) demand (D) is not static but is rather a function of time (t),. 2) Supply (S) is also time dependent, and thus is referred to as real demand semi-responsive supply or (rdsrs),. 3) Labor is dynamic (time dependent), and evolves with time,. This section will start with the definition of several variables. The first of these variables is real demand,. Real demand is a consequence of economic agent’s real needs and individual innovating approach to solve problems in time (t). Individual innovation is defined as solutions found by economic agents to their problems as stochastic elements that lead to demand for new products or services. Induced demand is in contrast to real demand. Induced demand can be defined as a desire to consume not be- cause of a genuine need for a product but as a result of media and industry manipulations. Conventional demand is shown in Figure 4(a). In Figure 4(a), (D), is the demand curve, (Q) is the quantity demanded, and (P) is price. Conventional demand is static and does not vary with time (t). The real demand is time dependent, and does not have a regular pattern, and its shape reflects the attitude of economic agents. Real demand peaks up for a certain period of time as more and more people believe that the solution to their problem is the product in the market. At this point, it is monotonically increasing with positive slope. peaks to its maximum after which it goes down for a certain period of time towards zero demand, as the result of changes in the individuals’ tastes, choices, and preferences that change in time (t). The downward segment of the is monotonically decreasing with negative slope. Zero real demand may last for a certain time, but this may not be a permanent condition. In time the same product may be the solution for another common problem; which would propel the real demand curve upwards, and the whole demand cycle starts all over again. Due to time dependent influences, real demand, keeps the same pattern irrespective of price changes. This is shown in (3) dimensions (Q, P, t), where (t) stands for time in Figure 4(b).

Figure 3. Lending to UK businesses, by business size. (a) Rate of grow in the stock of lending. Lending by UK MFIs, unless otherwise stated. Data cover lending in both sterling and foreign currency, expressed in sterling. Non seasonally adjusted. Further details are provided in the spreadsheet, available at: www.bank of england. co.uk/publications/Documents/other/monetary/lending touk businesses and individualsjuly 2014.xls; (c) Lending to UK SMEs with annual debit account turnover less than 25 million; (c) Lending by a BBA panel of lenders to SMEs in Great Birtain. SMEs are defined as businesses with turnover up to 25 million. Data are to March 2014; (d) Lending to UK large businesses with annual debit account turnover over 25 million.

(a)(b)

Figure 4. (a) Conventional demand; (b) Real demand (Dt).

Figure 4(b) demonstrates the evolution of real demand, with respect to price (P), and time (t). As is shown in Figure 4(b), real demand peaks at a fixed price at time, where, and is the maximum quantity demanded at time. then fluctuates until it reaches zero, , at time. peaks again, where is the maximum quantity demand-

ed at time. This process can go on for any finite time interval. Modeling of demand as a time dependent (stochastic) element seems to agree with consumer behavior in a laboratory environment, where fluctuations in demand for a given set of food products are concluded to be the result of time spent in doing the experimental tasks of product evaluation [25] . Conventional supply is shown in Figure 5(a).

The real demand semi-responsive supply or (rdsrs) denoted by imitates real demand approximately. As real demand increases (rdsrs) increases; during the slowdown of real demand, (rdsrs) increases at a very slow rate, while real demand goes to zero, (rdsrs) stabilizes and stays constant. At zero real demand, (rdsrs) stops definitely. (rdsrs) has one significant feature, surplus or (excess supply) is finite. (rdsrs) satisfies a fixed percentage of the market demand. If real demand increases beyond maximum production plus surplus, then supplier will not raise production, rather he will continue at maximum production level for a period of time till real demand for the product diminishes irreversibly. At this point the real value of the product has reached zero, and it is time to stop production definitively. Figure 5(b), shows the (rdsrs) pattern.

(a)(b)

Figure 5. (a) Conventional supply; (b) Supply as a function of real demand.

As is shown in Figure 5(b), during interval, and at a fixed price, (rdsrs) increases monotonically till time, is at its’ maximum supply level which corresponds to the maximum level of real demand. During the fluctuations in, remains fixed at. At time, drops to zero, when real demand is at (0). This cycle repeats itself, if real demand goes through a

new cycle. Empirical studies seem to confirm the behavior of (rdsrs). In Figure 6, the supply of physicians per 100,000 population stayed fixed for a certain period irrespective of fluctuations in demand [26] .

Finally, labor is redefined as intelligent labor,. Intelligent labor is synonym for dynamic technology. Dynamic technology refers to the level of intellectual prowess, strategic maneuvering, movement and mental and physical agility of an economic agent. High tech machinery, tools and instruments are referred to as physical technology. Physical technology can be considered as static technology. Physical technology relies on human innovation, thus is static at any interval of time. In contrast, dynamic technology is considered to be able to self- improve continually in time and thus dynamic. The three variables, real demand, , real demand semi-res- ponsive supply, , and intelligent labor, , are used in the proofs of the theorems below. It should be noted that in the proof of Theorem 1. Some notions from the traffic flow theory are borrowed. Real demand is taken to be analogous traffic on a road, [27] . This analogy is appropriate since the behavior of drivers when choosing a road is analogous to consumer preference as it is complete, reflexive and transitive. The road itself is analogous to the real demand semi-responsive supply,. This is an appropriate analogy since a road is a service supplier, and allows for a range of demand fluctuations, but has a fixed maximum supply capacity.

Theorem 1: Given that real demand exists and it is periodic; then real demand semi-responsive supply (rdsrs) should be bounded.

Proof: Real demand can be expressed in terms of flow and density. The flow of demand2 is the quantity demanded of any product per unit of time. The flow of demand is denoted by, (i) indicates product (i), where, and (t) stands for time. The flow of demand is given by:

(1)

Figure 6. Empirical evidence of time dependent supply.

is the quantity demanded of good (i) per unit of time (t). The density of demand is the quantity of product (i) demanded per square kilometers. The density of demand is denoted by, is demand per square kilometers. The density of demand is given by:

(2)

The speed with which demand propagates is formulated as the propagation of demand by kilometer per unit time (t):

(3)

The relationship between the flow and the density of demand is given by:

(4)

The flow of demand has (7) phases over time. These phases represent the attitude and strategic approach of economic agents towards demand. the attitude and strategic approach of economic agents is the stochastic (time dependent) elements involved in having demand such as taste, choice, preferences as they are acyclic, transitive, have a semi order property, and are complete. A phase is defined as the level of demand at time (t). The occurrence of a demand phase in time should have continuity, convexity, homogeneity, and translation-invariance properties. Given the prerequisites, phase (1) represents a situation where the number of goods demanded increases rapidly in time. During phases (2) & (3), the number of goods demanded increases moderately. In phase (4), the number of goods demanded decreases moderately. At this stage two possibilities arise; either demand increases or decreases. Phase (5) represents the possibility that demand increases. This phase is unstable and can only occur during a short period. Phase (6) represents the other possibility that the number of goods demanded drops to zero. Phase (7) represents a period when the number of goods demanded stays at zero. If the consumption of a product becomes the solution of certain economic problems for a number of agents, it is then possible to have a repetition of phases (1), (2), (3), (4), (6), and (7) over time. The probability of occurrence of phase (5) is considered small and thus is excluded from cyclical considerations. The many phases of the flow of demand are demonstrated in Figure 7.

The relationship between the flow and the density of demand is demonstrated in Figure 8. In phase (1) of Figure 8, the flow of demand increases more rapidly than the density of demand. The actual interpretation of this phase is that the number of consumers increases in time, but there are few consumers per square area. In phase (2) the flow of demand reaches its maximum for a given level of density. In phase (3), the flow of demand decreases while the density increases. This implies that demand has slowed down. In phase (4), the flow of de-

Figure 7. Different phases of the flow of real demand.

Figure 8. Flow vs. density of demand.

mand increases moderately, while the density decreases. This is an indicator of a general slowdown in demand. In phase (6), both the flow and the density of demand decrease rapidly. This implies that the slowdown in demand intensifies. In phase (7), both the flow and the density of demand are null. Demand ceases to exist. This relationship between the flow and the density of demand is adopted from the traffic flow theory. Why would demand for a product behave in the same way as the flow of traffic on a road segment? Consider the road segment as a product that is consumed by users (drivers). It is shown through various studies and data collected from various sites at different times of day, that traffic behaves in phases. This can be translated as the change in demand for a product that is a road segment. The assumption is that demand behaves in the same manner as traffic demand for the use of a road segment.

The same phase patterns can be observed if the density of demand is traced out in time. This is shown in Figure 9.

Real demand semi-responsive supply (rdsrs) can be defined in the same quantitative manner as demand. The flow of (rdsrs), is defined as the quantity of good (i) exchanged for good (j), , per unit time (t). This is expressed as follows:

(5)

The density of (rdsrs), is defined as the quantity of good (i) exchanged for good (j) per square kilometer,. The density of (rdrs) is an indicator of the preference for good (i) over good (j).

(6)

In the same manner the speed of (rdrs), is given by:

Figure 9. Density of demand vs. time.

(7)

is the speed with which good (i) is exchanged with good (j) per unit of time (t). is the radius in kilometer from the point of production or distribution. The speed of (rdsrs), is a measure of how fast good

(i) is exchanged with good (j). The relationship between the flow, and the density of (rdrs), is expressed as:

(8)

Following the analogy with the traffic flow theory, the flow of (rdsrs), demonstrates several phases in time (t). The (3) phases of are shown in Figure 10. Phase (1) is exactly similar to phase (1) of the flow of demand,. In phase (1), follows the behavior of. Phase (2) corresponds to phases (2), (3), & (4) of the flow of demand,. During phase (1), surplus is accumulated. The surplus plus a moderate supply level will see to the needs of phases (2), (3), and (4) of. Phase (3) of corresponds to phases (6) & (7) of the flow of demand,.

The speed-flow and speed-density relationship is demonstrated in Figure 11. The speed of (rdsrs) is at maximum when the density of (rdsrs), is zero. As the density, increases the speed

goes down until at maximum density, it reaches zero. This means that supply of good (j) has gone up. The speed goes down as the flow of supply, goes up. Once maximum flow is reached, the process reverses itself and goes down until it reaches zero.

Figure 12 shows how the flow of demand, , and the flow of (rdsrs), are related to each other.

From Figure 12, it is shown that the flow of demand, reaches its maximum at time (t = K). This is mathematically expressed as:

(9)

Given Equations [9] , and [4] , the density of demand, at point can be calculated. Given that the flow of demand is at its maximum point, then the density of demand is minimum at point, given a fixed speed,.

(10

Figure 10. Flow of (rdsrs) vs. time.

Figure 11. Density and flow of (rdsrs) vs. speed.

Figure 12. Relationship between the flow of demand and the flow of (rdsrs).

From Figure 12, the flow of (rdrs), reaches its maximum, at time (t = K). This is mathematically expressed as:

(11)

Surplus is denoted by. Surplus is defined as the difference between supply and demand,. The maximum flow of demand is equal to the maximum flow of supply, , when surplus. If this was not true, two cases could occur: 1) The maximum flow of real demand is greater than,. 2) It is less than,. is the maximum flow of demand other than. In case (1), the maximum flow of (rdrs), is less than, , if, and surplus is less than zero. In case (2), the maximum flow of (rdrs), is greater than, , if, and surplus is positive. In case (1), since implies that, it is in contradiction with the assumption that is maximum. In case (2), since, implies that, which is in contradiction with the assumption that at maximum. Therefore, is bounded at.□

Theorem 2: Given that exists and has multiple phases, and is semi-responsive and bounded, , then is finite in time,.

Proof: Let (T) be a time horizon, and let (T) be divided into (N) equal intervals of length,. Let during each. Let be a step function defined by Equation [12] :

(12)

The step function is shown in Figure 13.

During each interval two possibilities can occur:

1) for any,

2).

If (1) occurs, then is bounded, and has a unique maximum equal to. By Theorem 1, the maximum flow of supply is bounded and equal to, , and since is the maximum for the time horizon (T), then is bounded and thus finite in

time. If (2) occurs, then is not bounded, and thus does

Figure 13. Step function.

not have a unique maximum, which implies that is not bounded. This is in contradiction with the results of Theorem 1. Thus (2) cannot occur. (1) is the only possible case, and thus is bounded and finite in time,

. □

Theorem 3: Given that supply of any given product is semi-responsive, and bounded, and if the supply of the next product demonstrates the same attributes, and that there is always another product with the same supply characteristics and this process is repetitive, then growth occurs and is positive and monotonically increasing.

Proof: Let be (M) goods existing in a market during time (T). Let the flow and density of demand and supply for each one good be positive during each interval, , , and, , ,.

If, and, then, and. If , then the marginal flow and density of good,

, and, are zero, otherwise, , the marginal flow and density of good are positive. If, is true, growth per interval is defined as. Since, then growth is positive. Growth for the entire period

(T) is the sum of growth per interval, and is thus positive and monotonically increasing,. □

Theorem 4: Given that real demand exists, and supply is semi-responsive, bounded, and finite in time, then bank liquidity should be bounded.

Proof: Let time (T) be divided into (N) equal time intervals. Let the total number of labor be equal to,. Bank liquidity is the sum of savings. Savings (S) is formulated as. Income (I) per interval is equal to, where is the income of each labor, and is the total fixed number of labor per square kilometer. Let the density of labor3 be formulated as, be the number of labor per square kilometers at any interval. per labor is then equal to, where price per unit of labor is set fixed. Consumption (C) is equal to the density of demand, , times the price of good (i), ,. Profit is formulated as the density of supply multiplied by the price of good (i), , , where is the price of good (i) exchanged with good (j). Replacing consumption, in-

come, and profit by their equivalent formulation the following expression for savings is found:. The density of labor is at its maximum when the density of demand is at its maximum for at an specific time interval. By Theorem 1, the density of supply is at its maximum, when the density of demand is at its maximum. Thus as, the savings (S) can be reformulated in terms of the maximums as, and written in terms of the maximum of densities:. If

,

where (A) is a fixed value, then as, the level of savings (S) or liquidity is bounded by (A),. This means that during any time interval other than,. □

Theorem 5: Monopolistic and oligopolistic based economic activities are in conflict with small manufacturing and service activities.

Proof: The theorem is proved by showing that there are fundamental differences between demand and supply of oligopolies and small business activities. It is these differences that create incompatibility between the two

types of systems. On the demand side, let’s start the comparison by defining the flow of demand as the demand for good (i) produced by oligopolies per unit of time, and the density of demand

as the demand for good (i) produced by oligopolies per square kilometer. By definition oligopolies take a large share of the market. This is due to targeting high density population areas, controlling prices, and replacing labor with static technology. Therefore, the flow and density of demand of oligopolies are greater than that of small

producers, , and. This inequality is graphically demonstrated in Figure 14.

In Figure 14, is the flow of good (i) produced by oligopolies, is the flow of good (i) produced by small producers. The oligopoly marginal flow of demand is positive and increases in time

where, and (T) is a time horizon. This is due to incremental improvements in good (i), which create induced demand. The small producers’ marginal flow of demand is zero in time,

Figure 14. Oligopoly flow of demand vs. small producers.

. Substituting for the marginal flow of demand of small businesses,.

Comparison between the oligopolys’ and the small producers’ density of demand is shown in Figure 15. The density of demand of oligopoly is linearly increasing while the density of demand of small producer reaches a maximum and then reverses direction and goes to zero.

In Figure 15, is the density of good (i) produced by oligopolies, is the density of good (i) produced by small producers. Since the oligopoly marginal flow of demand is monotonically increasing in time,

the oligopoly marginal density of demand must be monotonically increasing in time, , with. Given that, then, and.

On the supply side, the flow, and the density of supply of oligopolies and small producers behave in very distinct ways from each other. As is shown in Figure 16, the flow and the density of supply of oligopoly increase linearly, while those of small pro-

ducers increase and then stay fixed at maximum, since supply is bounded and finite in time. This can also be seen from the comparison of marginal costs of oligopoly and small producer. In Figure 17, small producers

have a higher marginal cost (Cm2) at the beginning of their operation, when the density of supply is low. (Cm2) goes down as the density of supply goes up, and eventually goes up again reacting

to fluctuations in density of supply. The marginal cost (Cm1) of oligopolies, is higher than small businesses, but due to the economies of scale, the marginal cost (Cm1), goes down and stays down as the density of supply of oligopolies goes up. The same applies to labor and investment costs. In Figure 18, the differences in labor costs are demonstrated. For the oligopolies, the cost of labor goes down as more labor is replaced by static technology, while small businesses maintain a level of labor. In Figure 19, the differences in investment levels of oligopolies and small businesses are shown. In both Figure 18 and Figure 19, (1) Stands for small businesses, and (2) stands for oligopolies. Oligopolies have higher initial marginal costs (Cm1) which get smaller as time goes on. The oligopoly marginal flow of supply is positive and increases in time

Figure 15. Oligopoly density of demand vs. density of demand of small producer.

Figure 16. Oligopoly flow and density of supply vs. small producer flow and density of supply with respect to time (t) and space.

Figure 17. oligopoly marginal cost of production of vs. small producers’ marginal cost of production with respect to the density of supply of small businesses, and oligopolies.

Figure 18. Differences in labor pattern of small businesses and oligopolies.

Figure 19. Differences in investment between small businesses and oligopolies.

where. This is due to improvements in the production of good (i), using static technology. The small producers’ marginal flow of supply is zero in time,. Marginal flow of supply follows the same trend as the Marginal flow of demand. Substituting for the marginal flow of supply of small businesses,.

Since the oligopoly marginal flow of supply is monotonically increasing in time, the oligopoly marginal density of supply must be monotonically increasing in time, , with . Given that, then, and. In time given, the expansion of flow and density of demand and supply of oligopolies, it becomes difficult for small businesses to reenter the market, or for new businesses to enter. □

Theorem 6: Given the assumed patterns of the flow and the density of demand and supply of small and large economic operations, the two systems should function separately, but in parallel.

Proof: Let good (i) be produced by small businesses, and good (i') be produced by oligopolies. Let total mar-

ket demand be equal to (M). Let the quantity of good (i) produced by small businesses be, and the quantity of good (i') produced by oligopolies be, then. If, then,

and as the flow and density of demand and supply of oligopolies increases, the flow and density of demand and supply of small businesses diminishes, until at time (T), where (T) is equal to one demand cycle, the quantity of

good (i') be produced by oligopolies becomes equal to the total market demand (M),. This is demonstrated in Theorem 5. If, then there exists a total market demand for (i), , and a total market demand for good (i'), , such that, and. The evolution of the flow

and the density of demand and supply of either oligopoly, or small business have no impact on each other. Parallel operation of the two systems of small businesses and oligopolies, creates higher growth. From Theorem 3, growth due to the operation of small businesses is a function of the flow of supply, when it is at maximum. Therefore, it is positive. Growth due to the operation of oligopolies is positive, since the marginal flow of supply

is positive and increasing, as is shown in Theorem 3. Let growth due to small businesses be denoted by, and let growth due to oligopolies be denoted by. Total growth is then equal to,

if both small businesses and oligopolies function in parallel. If only one of the two systems functions, the growth

is always less than the growth reached by the parallel operation of the two systems together, , and, both growths being equal, the sum of the two growths is always greater, than its’ individual elements. □

4. Parallel-Multi-Layer Capitalism (Pmlc) as a Natural Outcome of the Theorems Introduced

There are (3) major economic models already in place. The PMLC model differs The “French” economic model”, the “Anglo-Saxon” economic model, and the “German exporting” economic model. Prominent characteristics of the “French” model are: 1) A government monopolistic system. 2) Peripheral oligopolies with a number of small subsidiaries. 3) Large banking operations with strong connections to the stock market to insure liquidity. 4) This system is dependent on an unbounded and monotonically increasing demand and supply. Prominent characteristics of the Anglo-Saxon economic model are: 1) Oligopolistic system geared towards the service industry. 2) Large banking operations with strong connections to the stock market as a major source of money supply in the form of asset prices and other financial instruments. 3) This system is dependent on an unbounded demand and supply in an asymmetric market. Prominent characteristics of the German export model are: 1) This system is based on asymmetric market mechanisms. 2) Demand is an increasing function of asymmetric information. 3) A large banking system based on stock market activities. 4) oligopolies with peripheral subsidiaries. 5) This system is dependent on an unbounded and monotonically increasing demand and supply in an asymmetric market. The reliance of all (3) economic systems on asymmetric markets, asymmetric information, and financial mechanisms render these systems vulnerable to economic crisis, [28] -[30] . Asymmetric markets, and asymmetric information introduces random effects in demand and supply. They can cause unanticipated inflationary, or deflationary prices that cause contractions in the pattern of demand and supply. Asymmetric information can cause adverse selection problems that weakens the financial market mechanisms and creates instability in terms of liquidity crisis.

The PMLC model is sustainable because it is based on bounded market share or bounded demand, bounded and stochastically constrained supply, and separation of small and large scale systems. Bounded demand and supply mean free entry of small businesses into the market. This system reduces the risks outlined above for the (3) existing economic systems. These risks are functions of the dependency of the economy on large market shares or demand. The Parallel Multi Layer system guarantees continuous employment and thus long term demand and supply of goods. The real value of any good has a finite duration; although demand is sustainable, demand for any single good is finite and disappears in time. Demand and supply are introduced as space-time dependent variables. Three main notions are introduced to give more depth to these variables. These notions are the flow, the density, and the speed of demand and supply. The flow of demand and supply is a measurable quantity given observational data. It concretizes the time dependency of demand and supply. The density is a measurable quantity given observational data and concretizes the space dependency of the two variables. The speed of propagation is a concrete way of showing space-time correlation of demand and supply. The three notions of the flow, density, and speed capture the non-linearity of demand and supply and their bounded nature in time. Since demand and supply are bounded, asymmetric markets, and asymmetric information cannot create discontinuities.

Demand exists and is nonlinear with multiple phases, that constitute a cycle. Supply is semi-responsive and bounded and finite in time. Bounded and finite in time supply reduces production costs by reducing excess supply. It encourages free entry of economic activities that create real values for which real demand exists. Each economic activity plans for an optimal operation period that corresponds to the real demand cycle. Each economic activity encourages and promotes the next generation of economic activities through maintaining a bounded and finite supply level. Since growth is the function of the flow of supply, then given that supply of any given product is semi-responsive, and bounded, and finite in time, and the supply of the next product has the same attributes, and there is always another product with the same supply characteristics and this process is cyclic, then growth is positive and monotonically increasing. Bounded and time finite supply, assure positive and monotonically increasing growth which in turn assures a dynamic technology base or labor. Dynamic technology base or labor is a conduit for smart, spontaneous, and productive innovations that assure entry of new products into the market.

The PMLC is based on the separation of large and small scale economic activities. This means that markets and products are differentiated. small and large economic activities work in different markets and produce different products. Large scale activities are allowed only for those economic activities for which economies of scale apply, and that static technology takes precedence over dynamic technology. From theorems (1 - 5), it is shown that the flow and the density of demand and supply of small and large scale economies are not compatible with each other if they are operating in the same market and produce the same products. This is demonstrated by the differences in the pattern of the marginal flow and the marginal density of supply and demand. In the long run, large economies eliminate small ones from the market. In addition to supply and demand that force the separation of small and large economic operations, other important variables are labor (dynamic technology), static technology (machinery), and investment. The distribution of these variables for each of the two systems differs significantly. This enforces the fact that the operability of these two systems within the same market and producing the same products is incompatible. Large and small scale economies can operate simultaneously if they operate in separate markets and produce different products. It is shown that if the two scale economies work in separate markets, then this would translate into a much higher growth. The difference in investment patterns of small and large scale operations dictates separate supporting financial structures.

A fundamental layer in the PMLC system is the banking system. Within the PMLC, small and large banks work in complete separation. The liquidity base of small banks is assured by the revenue produced by small and large scale economic activities respectively. Small scale banks set their own interest rates which are based on the risks involved. Bounded and finite supply, lower excess supply, and limited investment requirements, result in bounded profit levels. As a result small bank liquidity is bounded. This lowers the lending risks and significantly eliminates the adverse selection problem due to asymmetric information and asymmetric market mechanism. Large scale banks work exclusively with large scale economic activities and their interest rates are determined by central banks. This assures the sustainability of the large banking system.

5. Conclusions

A new model is introduced. The aim is to provide a basis for an economic structure that can be sustained given the non-linear nature of demand and supply. Many definitions are given to prepare a proper setting for the theorems that are introduced later. These theorems are meant to provide a structural framework for an economic system. This economic system is called Parallel-Multi-Layer Capitalism, or (PMLC). This name is chosen due to the fact that the economic structure proposed is based on the separation of small and large economic activities. Each type of activity is considered to be an economic layer, and since all layers operate within the framework of free competition, in the case of small businesses, and regulated competition in the case of monopolies, and oligopolies, they are considered to operate in a capitalistic system. In (PMLC), the major driving force is demand. Demand is the result of the needs of an intelligent and rational consumer that seeks to find solutions to problems that relate to his/her living conditions. Therefore, these needs are time and space dependent and so are the solutions. Solutions translate into real demand which is time dependent. Real demand is nonlinear and cyclic. Demand has a local maximum, and a local minimum during each cycle period.

The real value of a product is the degree of appropriateness, and usefulness of the product to the solution of consumer problems. A significant characteristic of small producers is their supply pattern. Supply of any product is bounded and finite in time. Each business activity keeps his share of the market fixed irrespective of fluctuations in demand. As demand increases supply increases, but it fixes itself at a local optimum of demand, thus eliminating the excess supply problem. This way whatever slack demand there is in the market is picked up by another small producer that will follow the same pattern of supply. It is a sure strategy for allowing the entries of new small producers in the market. Each business in the market decides on a fixed period of operational time. The advantage is that they can keep their costs manageable. The marginal, total, and average costs are reasonably incremented over time. The variable costs are stable during the life of the business. Productivity remains at its highest level during this period. Meanwhile, the next generation of goods mature to the point where they can enter the market. The PMLC system also allows for a parallel system of large scale operations. The condition imposed is that large economic activities should provide for services and create industries that differ from those of small businesses. Banks are also separated to serve small and large economic activities. The main difference is the liquidity base. For small banks the liquidity base is the savings of individuals and small producers’ profits. Their lending policy is based on interest rates as a function of risk. Limited profits and savings assure low level lending risks. Large banks have large liquidity base. They rely on large scale economic activities to secure their money supply. Their lending policy is based on interest rates set by central banks. Time will tell if PMLC model marks the maturation age of capitalism.

References

  1. The Economist. 21st-27th February 2009.
  2. Wallerstein, I. (1979) Aufstieg und zukünftiger Niedergang des kapitalistischen Weltsystems: Zur Grundlegung ver gleichender Analyse. In: Senghaas, D., Ed., Kapitalistische Weltökonomie: Kontroversen über ihren Ursprung und ihre Entwick lungsdynamik, Suhrkamp Verlag, Frankfurt am Main, 31-67.
  3. Althusser, L. (1978) Le capital. Maspero Publishing, Paris.
  4. Beckert, J. (2012) Capitalism as a System of Contingent Expectations: Toward a Sociological Micro Foundation of Political Economy. Max-Planck-Institut für Gesellschaftsforschung, Köln.
  5. Walras, L. (1954) Elements of Pure Economics. Routledge Publishing, Cornwall.
  6. Eatwell, J., Milgate, M. and Newman, P. (1987) Walras’s Theory of Capital. The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, Vol. 1. Macmillan Press Ltd., London. http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/9780230279803
  7. Blinder, A.S. (2008) Keynesian Economics. Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. 2nd Edition, Library of Economics and Liberty, Indianapolis.
  8. Keynes, J.M. (2008) The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. BN Publishing, Thousand Oaks.
  9. Say, J.B. (1834) A Treatise on Political Economy. Grigg & Elliott Publishing, Philadelphia.
  10. Saiduzzaman, S. (2014) The Theory of Diminishing Return.
  11. Panetta, F., Angelini, P., Grande, G., Levy, A., Perli, R., Yesin, P., et al. (2006) The Recent Behavior of Financial Market Volatility. BIS Papers, No. 29, Monetary and Economic Department, Bank for International Settlements Press & Communications, Basel.
  12. Bessis, J. (2003) Risk Management in Banking. John Wiley & Sons Publishing, Hoboken.
  13. Committee on Small Business (2008) Small Business Economic Outlook: Assessing Current Conditions and Chal- lenges to Growth. 110th US Congress, Washington DC, 18 April 2008, 110-192.
  14. Khoshyaran, M. (2004.) The New Capitalists: A Structural Change from the Stock Market Economy to the Free Market Economy. Physica A, 344, 14-18. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.physa.2004.06.080
  15. Khoshyaran, M. (2003) The Role of Small Business Based Structures in Promoting Innovation and Creating Employment, as Compared to Oligopolistic Based Structures. Proceedings of the Wild@Ace Conference, Torino, 3-4 October 2003, 350-372.
  16. Marshall, A. (1920) Principles of Economics. Macmillan Publishing, London.
  17. Pindyck, R.S. and Rubinfled, D.L. (2005) Microeconomics. Pearson Publishing, London.
  18. Varian, H.R. (1996) Intermediate Microeconomics. Norton Publishing, New York.
  19. Haubrich, J.G. (1994) Bank Diversification: Laws and Fallacies of Large Numbers. Working Paper 9417, Federal Re- serve Bank of Cleveland.
  20. Bessis, J. (2003) Banking Risk Management. John Wiley & Sons Publishing, Hoboken.
  21. Mishkin, F.S. (2006) The Economics of Money, Banking, and Financial Markets. Pearson-Addison-Wesley Publishers, London.
  22. Samuelson, P.A. (1963) Risk and Uncertainty: A Fallacy of Large Number. Acta Mathematica Scientia, 9, 1-6.
  23. Khoshyaran, M. (2006) The Parallel Universe of Economics. FUR 12th International Conference, Foundations and Applications of Utility, Risk, and Decision Theory Conference, Rome, 22-26 June 2006, 1-10.
  24. (2014) Trends in Lending. Bank of England Report, London.
  25. Fevrier, P. and Visser, M. (2004) A Study of Consumer Behavior Using Laboratory Data. Experimental Economics, 7, 93-114. http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:1026266122863
  26. Deber, R., Baumann, A., Gamble, B. and Laporte, A. (2010) Supply and Demand of Health Workers in an Economic Downturn. IMWC, International Medical Workforce Collaboration, New York City, 2-5 May 2010, 43 p.
  27. Hall, F.L. (1975) Traffic Flow Theory. Transportation Research Board (TRB), Special Report 165, Chapter 2, Federal Highway Administration, Washington DC.
  28. Mankiw, N.G. (1986) The Allocation of Credit and Financial Collapse. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101, 455-470. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1885692
  29. Minsky, H.P. (1972) Financial Stability Revisited: The Economics of Disaster. Reappraisal of the Federal Reserve Discount Mechanism, 3, 95-136.
  30. Mishkin, F.S. (1978) The Household Balance Sheet and the Great Depression. Journal of Economic History, 38, 918- 937. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0022050700087167

NOTES

2Demand refers to real demand.

3Labor refers to intelligent labor or dynamic technology.