Open Journal of Political Science
Vol.06 No.03(2016), Article ID:68099,26 pages
10.4236/ojps.2016.63026
The Nordic Countries: From the Rokkan Model (“uns”) to the Touraine Model (“ich”)
Jan Erik Lane
Fellow with Public Policy Institure, Belgrade, Serbia
Copyright © 2016 by author and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.
This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution International License (CC BY).
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/
Received 7 April 2016; accepted 5 July 2016; published 8 July 2016
ABSTRACT
Comparative politics like any comparative studies needs models with which to interpret lots of facts. Theoretical models orientate the data towards parsimony in understanding of key relationships and focus the debate on key issues. Politics in the Nordic countries used to be modelled as an exceptionally stable set of multi-party systems, based upon social cleavages as well as PR in a unitary state with comprehensive decentralisation to the local governments (communes). This model owes much to Norwegian social scientist Stein Rokkan, who traces the basic cleavages (ethnic, religious, class) to historical legacies and social organisation of civil society. Its key feature is electoral stability: “frozen party systems”. However, recently the processes of European integration and globalisation have undermined Scandinavian exceptionalism, resulting in rising political instability, electoral volatility and populist or anti-foreigner parties with considerable support. The typical political hegemony of the Social Democratic Parties (“Arbeiterbewegung”) is a thing of the past, as governments come and go in rapid fashion. As these societies have adapted to the pressures from global capitalism, inequalities in income and wealth have short up. Yet, the Nordic welfare state has been trimmed but not abolished, as all countries have accepted some of the basic ideas in both New Public Management and further regional or local decentralisation. Adding these major changes together, we must chose another theoretical model, namely the Alain Touraine thesis about the weakening of political sociology and firm social institutions on the one hand as well as the spread of individualism and egoism on the other hand―“la fin de la societe”. The recent flows of migrants to Scandinavia and Finland have further increased centrifugal tendencies.
Keywords:
Nordic Countries (Sweden, Denmark, Norway and Finland), Political Stability to Instability, EU, Governments, Elections, Civil Society, Affluence, Migrants, Model World of Rokkan to That of Touraine, Svante Ersson
1. Introduction
“Norden” is the label for the five countries situated in northern Europe comprising Denmark (5, 6 million people in 2015), Finland (5, 5), Iceland (0, 3), Norway (5, 1) and Sweden (9, 8). The land area covered by these five nation states is quite extensive, especially if one adds Greenland (2,166,000 sq. km) and the Faroe Islands (1393 sq. km), which are autonomous areas within the
The Nordic countries have strong links with each other, economically and politically. They co-ordinated their policies by means of the Nordic Council, formed in 1952, which had resulted in the harmonisation of regulations and a free labour market. They also to some extent act in a collective fashion in international bodies, although their membership of various supranational bodies varies. Thus Denmark, Iceland and Norway were members of NATO since 1949. Norway and Iceland are not members of the EU, though as EFTA members they joined the European Economic Area (EEA) which came into effect in 1994.
Relationships between the Nordic countries and Europe have not been entirely smooth. A number of referenda have been conducted on this issue and the result is that only Finland is a member of both the EU and the Eurozone. Denmark but not Norway became a member of the European Community in 1973, while Sweden and Finland entered the European Union (EU) in 1995. The Danish “No” in 2000 in the referendum on joining the European Monetary Union (EMU) as well as a similar referendum in Sweden in 2003 indicated that Norden was far from endorsing full participation in all aspects of the European project. Table 1 displayed the outcomes of the referenda on this issue between 1972 and 2015.
Thus, three Nordic countries are members of the EU, while the other two countries are part of the EEA. Only Finland has decided to endorse the European Union completely as it has entered the EMU, accepting the Euro. Both Denmark and Sweden has opted out of the EMU. All the Nordic countries have been part of the Schengen Accord since 2001―Norway and Iceland on an associated basis. This partial integration has, however, opened up a process of “Europeanisation” of the Nordic states in terms of public administration and policies.
The Danish, Norwegian and Swedish languages are quite similar, whereas Finnish belongs to an entirely different language family, although to some extent also Icelandic is distinct. All the Nordic countries have been ethnically homogeneous, although there exist substantial and growing minorities, in particular immigrants but also small Sami populations. Multiculturalism has been fostered by globalisation and a firm but quick naturalisation policy. Thus, all the Scandinavian capitals and Helsinki have today sizeable groups with foreign ethnic origins.
“Scandia” was the old Latin name for the three countries of northern Europe: Denmark, Norway and Sweden (the “Scandinavian countries”) had already formed states or kingdoms during the high medieval period.
Table 1. Referendums on relations with the European Union, 1972-2015.
when
The standard model for the interpretation of Nordic politics is the so-called Scandinavian, or Nordic, model. In the international literature it has been pointed out that Nordic politics does not fit conventional democracy models such as the Anglo-Saxon Westminster model or the Continental consensus model. The Scandinavian model comprises a distinct set of institutions, covering the state and local government, the party system, interest organizations and the economy.
It is not easy to unpack the concept of a specific governance model in Norden, as its features vary somewhat from one country to another. The Scandinavian model emerged out of the Great Depression of the inter-war years around 1935, became hegemonic after the Second World War but ran into increasing difficulties beginning with the early 1980s, when Olson (1990) asked about How Bright were the Northern Light, and apparently the model revived again in the 2000s (The Economist, 2013) . Its core is a blend of compromise politics, local government autonomy and corporatism, where party competition is nested together with political and social co-ope- ration. Scandinavian-model politics was initiated by red-green cooperation in Denmark and Sweden in 1933 , in Norway in 1935 and in Finland in 1937.
The Scandinavian model developed from small-scale political co-operation across the deep cleavages between the socialist and the non-socialist camps and the urban and rural opposition into a large-scale institutional blueprint combining a universal welfare state with an efficient capitalist economy. The Scandinavian model involves a substantial policy commitment dating back to the 1930s, when a social pact was agreed upon by the major players, replacing the conflict between capital and labour as well as between city dwellers and rural farmers with a compromise that protected the institutions of the market economy but allowed for large-scale government activity in relation to unemployment, protection of peasants as well as social security. What distinguishes the Nordic welfare state is the generality and comprehensiveness of the programmes. The outcome has been the characteristic feature of a model with a large public sector involving a strong emphasis on more equal distributions of income as well as promoting gender equality. The economies of Nordic countries have overall done well, but
Politically speaking, the institutions of the Scandinavian model express compromise politics while at the same time the overall constitutional frame remains the
It should be pointed out that Finnish politics has been somewhat different, as it has housed so-called consociational devices, or grand coalitions. Not only is there a strong tendency towards oversized government coalitions, but specific constitutional rules have called for qualified majority decisions on a regular basis. Up to 1992 a third of the MPs in the Finnish Parliament (67 out of 200) could delay the passage of a Bill adopted by parliament until parliament assembled again the next year. This extraordinary consociational device was paralleled by a requirement of a two-thirds majority for tax decisions. Both these institutions were though abolished in 1992.
In addition,
2. Constitutions: Rule of Law
All the Nordic countries have written constitutions. As the Norwegian constitution is the oldest, dating back to 1814, it comprises the obsolete rules of a constitutional monarchy and lacks formal recognition of the principle of parliamentarianism. Iceland’s Basic Law of 1944 outlines a republic based upon parliamentarianism. The Danish constitution of 1953 contains a strong referendum institution, which requires a referendum for constitutional changes, whereas the Norwegian Basic Law stipulates a two-thirds majority in the Parliament for such decisions. The old 1919 Finnish constitution demanded a majority, then a two-thirds majority, with an election in between, or a five-sixths majority followed by a two-thirds majority decision confirmation; the present Constitution from year 2000 has not been changed in this respect. In
The issue of revising the Icelandic Constitution surfaced as a consequence of the financial crisis. A Constitutional Assembly was elected in 2010, but since the Supreme Court invalidated the result a Constitutional Council was decided by the Althing in 2011. This Council drafted a new Constitution during 2011 and it was due for a referendum in 2012 where a majority voted for the draft although the turnout was only 49%. The draft was not voted on in the new Althing elected in 2013, mainly because of resistance from the new cabinet.
The referendum institution undoubtedly plays a prominent role in Danish politics. Whereas in
The judicial branch of government in Norden is framed upon the conception of rule of law and legal integrity. There is room for some independent legal review by the ordinary courts. No country has a constitutional court, though human rights have constitutional protection.
The five countries now have unicameral National Assemblies; bicameralism were abolished in 1953 in Denmark and 1970 in Sweden, while quasi-bicameral chambers ended in Iceland in 1991 and 2009 in Norway. All forms of public power derive ultimately from Acts of parliament, which principle of legislative supremacy has not prohibited a fairly extensive system of local government autonomy.
The chief characteristic of Nordic politics-the combination of Westminster politics with consensus politics- does not involve a once-and-for-all fixed structure of political institutions. The actual working out of the combination of adversarial and compromise politics shifts over time and differs from one country to another in Norden, the adversarial atmosphere sometimes dominating whereas at other times the compromise climate. Changes do occur, as we have noted with
3. Elections
Scandinavian democracy rests upon an election system strongly geared to proportional representation, underlining both extensive citizen participation in elections and the capacity of minorities to organize and become represented. The Scandinavian model does not accept any form of majoritarian electoral formula, as all the States attempt to achieve as high a level of correlation between votes and seats as possible. The minimum voting age is eighteen years. The mechanism of adversarial politics, the plurality formula, has not attracted much attention in the five Nordic countries―Iceland being an exception up to 1959. Although discussed somewhat at the time of the introduction of democracy around the end of the First World War, the electoral system has recognised the typical feature of the party systems: the large degree of fractionalisation. The general emphasis is upon strict proportionality, as a system of regional mandates is used to correct for lack of proportionality in the election results. Only Sweden employs a rather high 4 percent threshold to counteract excessive fractionalisation, with the Danish Parliament using a 2 percent threshold; Iceland and Norway applies a 5 percent threshold for compensatory seats, while it is 12 percent in Sweden. As it had been argued that the political parties dominate the elections to the exclusion of personal choice, the Finnish system has a strong element of personal choice for the voter, which is also true for the Danish system, while an element of personal choice (semi-open lists) has lately been introduced in the other Nordic countries. Yet Nordic politics adhere to the model of party governance, as party discipline tends to be high.
The process of translating social cleavages into political life is closely tied up with the development of the political institutions constituting Nordic democracy. Rokkan identified three thresholds that were crucial to the establishing of a democratic regime: extension of the franchise (male and female), proportionality in representation and executive control. The timing of these three thresholds in Norden was:
1. Male suffrage: 1898 Norway, 1906 Finland, 1909 Sweden, 1915 Denmark, Iceland.
2. Female suffrage: 1906 Finland, 1913 Norway, 1915 Denmark, Iceland, 1921 Sweden.
3. Proportional representation: 1906 Finland, 1909 Sweden, 1915 Denmark, 1959 Iceland.
4. Parliamentarianism: 1884 Norway, 1901 Denmark, 1904 Iceland, 1917 Sweden, 1919 Finland.
The electoral systems in Norden really result in proportional outcomes. For Denmark we have 98 percent of proportionality, for Finland 93 percent, for Iceland 95 percent, for Norway 94 percent, and finally for Sweden 96 percent in the elections hold during the period after 1991. Since
There can be little doubt that the strong institutionalization of proportionality in Nordic election rules has been conducive to multipartism as well as a high level of electoral participation. The average turnout for the post-war period has hovered around 85 percent in
From the introduction of democratic regimes around the First World War the typical feature has been the five-party system, with some variations between nations and over time. On the left there were the social democratic and the communist parties, while the non-socialist parties typically comprised conservative, liberal and agrarian parties. Considering the mere number of political parties represented in parliament the average figure for the years 1945-2014 is higher for Denmark and Finland, 8.8 and 8.1 respectively, than for Norway, with 6.7, Sweden, with 5.9 and Iceland with 5.6. There is a clear trend towards an increase in fractionalisation.
Typical of Nordic politics is moderate fractionalisation, which can be measured by the effective number of parties, which hovers around 5.0. Thus,
The Nordic political cultures have an activist civic orientation as expressed in relatively high, although decreasing, levels of electoral participation and in the strong backing for several political parties. The Nordic countries display a higher turnout, but in terms of party system fractionalisation, the Nordic countries are not different from other European countries (Tables 2-5).
4. Parties and Party Strategies
From the very beginning of the democratic regime the socio-economic cleavage or left-right division has been dominant in Scandinavian politics. Political parties have been formed according to this dimension and several of the political issues developed around this cleavage. Against the socialist bloc comprising a large Social Democratic party plus one more left-wing party, whether a left-Socialist party or a Communist party, has stood a non-socialist bloc consisting of a Conservative party plus a few centre parties. Only in
The size of the Social Democratic parties varies from the large ones in Sweden and Norway to smaller ones in Denmark, Finland and Iceland. The left-socialist parties in Denmark and Norway are not insignificant. The
Table 2. Elections to parliament in Denmark, 1945-2011.
Notes: Communist: DKP: Communist Party (Danmarks Kommunistiske Parti); EL: Unity List (Enhedslisten). Left-socialists: SF: Socialist People’s Party (Socialistisk Folkeparti). Social Democrats: SD: Social Democrats (Socialdemokratiet). Liberals: RV: Radical Left (Radikale Venstre); CD: Centre Democrats (Centrumdemokraterne); LA: Liberal Alliance (Liberal Alliance). Agrarians: V: Agrarian Liberal (Venstre). Christian: KD: Christian Democrats (Kristendemokraterne). Conservative: KF: Conservative People’s Party (Konservativt Folkeparti). Populist: DF: Danish People’s Party (Dansk Folkeparti); FrP: Progress Party (Fremskridtspartiet).
non-socialist spectrum covers a Conservative party, a Liberal party and an Agrarian party (Centre party), complemented by Religious parties and recently by Populist parties in the 1970s. The electoral outcomes of the various so-called bourgeois or non-socialist parties have fluctuated considerably over time. The Green parties dating from the 1980s, to begin with stood in-between the two blocks, but tend nowadays to lean more to the left.
The left-right dimension still has an impact on Scandinavian politics, although there are indications that its relevance has decreased over time. One major post-Second World War trend is the striking decline in class voting. It may be measured by the proportion voting for the left, i.e. Socialist or Communist parties, among the working classes. In
Table 3. Elections to parliament in Finland, 1945-2011.
Notes: Communists: SKDL: Finnish People’s Demo Cratic League (Suomen Kansan Demokraattinen Liitto); VAS: Left Alliance (Vasemmeistoliitto). Green: VIHR: Green League (Vihreä Liitto). Social Democrats: SDP: Social Democratic Party of Finland (Suomen Sosialidemokraattinen Puolue). Swede: SFP: Swedish Peoples Party (
Table 4. Elections to parliament in Norway, 1945-2013.
Notes: Communist: NKP: Norwegian Communist Party (Norges Kommunistiske Parti). Left-socialist: SV: Socialist Left Party (Sosialistik Venstreparti). Green: MDG: Green Party (Miljøpartiet De Grønne). Social Democrats: Ap: Labour Party (Arbeiderpartiet). Agrarian: Sp: Centre Party (Senterpartiet). Christian: KrF: Christian People’s Party (Kristelig Folkepartei). Liberal: V: Liberals (Venstre). Populist: FrP: Progress Party (Fremskrittspartiet). Conservative: H: Conservative Party (Høyre).
Table 5. Elections to parliament in Sweden, 1944-2014.
Notes: Communist: VPK: Left Party Communists (Vänsterpartiet Kommunisterna); V: Left Party (Vänsterpartiet). Feminist: FI: Feminist Initiative (Feministiskt Initiativ). Green: MP: Environmental Party―the Greens (Miljöpartiet De Gröna). Social Democrats: SAP: Swedish Social Democratic Workers’ Party (Sveriges Socialdemokratistika Arbetarparti). Agrarian: CP: Centre Party (Centerpartiet). Liberal: FP: People’s Party―the Liberals (Folkpartiet-Liberalerna). Christian: KD: Christian Democrats (Kristdemokraterna). Moderate: M: Moderate Unity Party (Moderata Samlingspartiet). Populist: NyD: New Democrats (Ny Demokrati); SD: Sweden Democrats (Sverigedemokraterna).
That class voting is on the retreat is a long-run tendency that admits short-term fluctuations. Thus one may expect a rise in class voting in periods of economic crisis, as in the early 1990s or in the mid 2000s. Still, it is a fact that the socio-economic cleavage, based upon material foundations, tends to be replaced in Norden by another kind of cleavage, summarised in the theme of post-materialism or new politics. Data indicate that post- materialist values have an anchor, especially among the post-war generations. However, the other major trend since 1945, besides de-alignment along the class cleavage, has been the realignment of the electorate according to the logic of new politics.
Party government is institutionalised in Norden, political action being overwhelmingly dominated by political parties, which channel electoral participation by means of list voting. The Nordic party systems express multi- dimensional issues, involving one strong alignment between the left and the right and less strong additional alignments expressed partly by the parties in the non-socialist bloc but also by the Green party.
A majority of the parties operating on the Nordic political scene date back to the 1920s and earlier, including the Liberal and Conservative parties as well as the Social Democratic parties. The Norwegian Venstre and Høyre were formed back in the 1880s, while the Danish Venstre goes back to 1871. The Swedish and Finnish non-socialist parties were built up in the years around 1900. The Social Democratic parties were founded around the same time, with the Danish party the oldest (1871) and the Finnish party the youngest (1899). The Agrarian and the Communist parties made their appearance shortly before and after the First World War, respectively. The Finnish Agrarian party is the oldest (1907) and the Norwegian Agrarian party the youngest (1920), while the Swedish Communist Party is the oldest (1917) and the Norwegian Communist Party the youngest (1923).
The political parties in
4.1. Size of Traditional Parties
These parties, representing six different party types if the ethnic Swedish-language People’s Party in Finland is added, have played a dominant role since the early 1920s. Looking at electoral support for these parties, here called the “traditional” parties, from the 1940s to the 2010s one may establish that these parties totally dominated the political scene until the phenomenon of new politics arrived in Norden in the 1970s.
In the 1940s, the traditional parties reached very high levels of support, roughly 91 percent in Norway (the Christians excluded) and 94 percent in Denmark, but 99 percent in Finland and Sweden. They more or less managed to retain that support level until the 1970s, when the overall pattern started to change. The average scores for these parties were much lower already in the 1970s for Denmark and Norway, at 70 percent and 73 percent, and in the 1980s for Finland at 83 percent, but it was not until the early 1990s that their share of the vote was down also in Sweden, scoring 84 percent. And this pattern holds true also for the early 2000s, where the traditional parties have a stronger standing in Finland and Sweden (77 and 82 percent) than what is the case in Denmark and Norway (70 and 61 percent). One of the most conspicuous aspects of recent Nordic politics is the dealignment as well as the realignment of the electorate around new parties. The process of increasing instability manifested itself in a few major changes in the party systems up to the early 2000s: (1) the decline of the social-democratic parties; (2) the introduction of new political parties; (3) the emergence of left-wing socialist parties, partly as a transformation of the Communist parties. As a result, voter volatility is up sharply, both gross and net volatility.
The average support for Social Democratic parties between 1945 and 2014 was as high as 43 percent in
Among the non-socialist parties, the Conservative parties have managed to attract considerable support from one election to another, amounting to almost a fifth of the electorate. Between 1945 and 2014 the average outcome was 15 percent in Denmark, 18 percent in Finland, 21 percent in Norway and 19 percent in Sweden, where the conservative party reached 23 percent in 2014. With increasing voter volatility, the fortunes of the Conservative party has, however, varied much, with a low of 5 percent support in Denmark in 2011 as well as the Norwegian Conservative party suffering a setback from 32 percent in 1981 to 14 percent in 2005 and coming back in 2013 with 27 percent. The overall trend for the Liberal parties in Norden is in the downward direction. Average support in 1945-2014 was much lower in Denmark, with 7 percent, Finland, with 3 percent, and Norway, with 7 percent; Sweden was the only exception, with an average of 13 percent support for the Liberal Party. The trend for the last elections indicates a further reduction in electoral support for the Liberal parties.
One of the distinctive traits of Nordic politics is the strong political institutionalisation of an agrarian movement. Not only were special Agrarian parties organized early in the process of introducing mass politics, but they have been successful in retaining considerable electoral support, especially since they identified themselves as centre parties. The strongest centre party is to be found in
4.2. Introduction of New Parties
The transformation of Nordic politics started with the setbacks for the traditional parties, beginning with the 1973 “earthquake” elections in Denmark and Norway, and continued in the 1991 election in Sweden. The first new parties on the political scene were the religious parties (beginning with the Christian People’s Party, KRF, in Norway) and the left-socialist parties (starting with the Socialist People’s Party, SF, in Denmark). The other new parties entering the political arena were Populist parties on the one hand and the Green parties on the other. The amount of support given to Populist parties in
Religious parties were created in all the four major Nordic countries. They are now somewhat larger in
The relatively large left-socialist parties in Denmark and Norway, scoring support of 9 percent and 8 percent in the 2000s, respectively, have not suffered from the decline of communism, as they had already marked their distance from the communist parties in the 1960s; the Norwegian SV was thus able to enter government for the first time in 2005 in coalition with the Social democrats and the Agrarians to step down after the 2013 election. The Danish SF also for the first time entered government in 2011 but had to withdraw in early 2014.
The populist parties started to receive support in the early 1970s in
The Green parties have met with some success, where most support was provided in Finland in 2007, at 9 percent with the party being member of government between 1995-2002 and from 2007. In Sweden the greens entered the Parliament in 1988, did not reach the threshold in the 1991 election, then returned to the Parliament in 1994. In the 2014 election, the Swedish Greens scored 7 percent. There also exist Green parties in
Nordic politics has been much focused on the major changes taking place within the party systems from the early 1970s onwards. The rise of new parties and the decline of the traditional parties indicate increasing instability in the party systems, making elections more unpredictable as the electorate is more prone to change its allegiance from one election to another.
4.3. Sharp Rise in Voter Volatility Both Gross and Net
Looking at data over net as well as gross volatility gives support to such a conclusion, gross volatility measuring how the voters move from one party to another and net volatility measuring the resultant changes in overall support for a party. One aspect of Scandinavian exceptionalism by comparison with the Continental countries in Europe was a long period of low volatility scores, beginning in the late 1940s and ending in the early 1970s in
In the 1950s net volatility amounted to 6 percent in Denmark and 4 percent in Norway, but during the 1970s it rose to 15 percent in both countries, gross volatility reaching 37 percent in Denmark and 25 percent in Norway. For
The tendency towards party system instability has induced a reassessment of the pros and cons of party government. There is more of scepticism today about political parties, which is expressed in less of trust for political parties in 2012 than what was the case in 2004. There is also a decline in party membership with a general downward trend in the four larger Nordic countries. Looking at data comparing membership as percent of voters in 1980 and early 2000s, this trend is marked in Norway, where the ratio in 1980 was 15 but 5 in 2013, and in 2013 this ratio is similar to what we find in Finland (7), Denmark (4) and Sweden (3), although Iceland deviates with a much higher ratio being over 20 percent. It is still the case that trusts in political parties and membership rates are higher among the Nordic countries than in other European countries.
Although there have been important changes in the party systems during the last decades, it should be emphasized that the traditional parties still have a rather strong standing. The general ability of these parties to adapt to changing circumstances is of major importance, as, for instance, one crucial institutional factor was the introduction of public funding of political parties. Legislation allowing State funding of political parties was introduced first in Sweden in 1966, followed by Finland in 1967, Norway in 1970 and Denmark only in 1987. Available data from the election years around 2010 suggest that the dependency on public funding is highest among Norwegian parties (71 percent) followed by Swedish parties (59 percent) and lowest with Danish parties (48 percent). There is also a large variation among the parties in their reliance on public funds, with high rates for the Swedish Left Party, the Danish Peoples Party and the Norwegian Progress Party with lower rates for the Conservatives in
4.4. Party Strategies: Ideology and Issues
The strategies followed by the political parties may be characterized in terms of the distinction between ideology (reliance on the party programme) and tactics (maximization of parliamentary influence and impact on the executive). Important for the choice of strategy has been, on the one hand, the size of the party in parliament, and on the other, the political relevance of the party, i.e. its position on the left-right political scale. Parties stressing tactics are to be found among the traditional parties, with the exception of the communist parties. The new parties underline ideology more, although the religious parties have recently mixed tactics with ideological purity, as secularisation appears unstoppable in Norden. Looking at some major issues during the post-war era, it is evident that the ideological dimension has played a minor role while the tactical component has played the decisive role in deciding the party orientation to these issues. The Social Democratic parties and the Conservatives have adopted catch-all strategies.
Yet data on party policy alignment show that the right-left dimension still is the prevailing mode for the voters to position themselves in relation to the political parties. Tables 6-9 show how voters placed themselves in the four major Nordic countries during the early 2000s. It is also the case that this pattern is quite similar for the four countries: on the left the leftist or the former Communist parties and on the right the Conservative parties, while the Social Democrats, Christians, Liberals and Centre parties tend to occupy the political centre, and the Greens are left of centre; the Populist parties in Denmark and Norway are on the right, whereas the populist parties in Finland and Sweden more leans to the centre (Tables 6-9).
Table 6. Left-right placement of parties in Denmark.
Notes: EL: Unity List (Enhedslisten); SF: Socialist People’s Party (Socialistisk Folkeparti). SD: Social Democrats (Socialdemokratiet). RV: Radical Left (Radikale Venstre). CD: Centre Democrats (Centrumdemokraterne). KD: Christian Democrats (Kristendemokraterne). LA: Liberal Alliance (Liberal Alliance). DF: Danish People’s Party (Dansk Folkeparti). V: Agrarian Liberal (Venstre). KF: Conservative People’s Party (Konservativt Folkeparti).
Table 7. Left-right placement of parties in Finland.
Notes: VAS: Left Alliance (Vasemmeistoliitto). SDP: Social Democratic Party of Finland (Suomen Sosialidemokraattinen Puolue). VIHR: Green League (Vihreä Liitto). PS: True Finns (Perussuomalaiset). KD: Christian Democrats of Finland (Suomen Kristillisdemokraatit). KESK: Centre Party (Agrarian) (Keskustapuoiue). SFP: Swedish People’s Party (
Table 8. Left-right placement of parties in Norway.
Notes: SV: Socialist Left Party (Sosialistik Venstreparti). Ap: Labour Party (Arbeiderpartiet). Sp: Centre Party (Senterpartiet). V: Liberals (Venstre). KrF: Christian People’s Party (Kristelig Folkepartei). FrP: Progress Party (Fremskrittspartiet). H: Conservative Party (Høyre).
Table 9. Left-right placement of parties in Sweden.
Notes: V: Left Party (Vänsterpartiet). FI: Feminist Initiative (Feministiskt Initiativ). MP: Environmental Party―the Greens (Miljöpartiet De Gröna). SAP: Swedish Social Democratic Workers’ Party (Sveriges Socialdemokratistika Arbetarparti). SD: Sweden Democrats (Sverigedemokraterna). CP: Centre Party (Centrepartiet). FP: People’s Party-the Liberals (Folkpartiet-Liberalerna). KD: Christian Democrats (Kristdemokraterna). M: Moderate Unity Party (Moder ata Samlingspartiet).
Issue voting may be on the rise due to the fact that social heterogeneity has both increased and decreased. As the Nordic countries are facing a larger number of foreign residents entering their countries, this has added cultural heterogeneity to the social structure. Foreign population as a percentage of the entire population have increased relatively rapidly during the last decades. Around 2000, they amounted to 5 percent in Denmark, Norway and Sweden, whereas 3 percent in Finland, to increase around 2010 to 8 percent in Norway, 7 percent in Sweden and 6 percent in Denmark, remaining at 3 percent in Finland. At the same time the Nordic countries have extended citizenship to large proportions of the immigrants, so that the share of the countries’ populations of foreign born is 15 percent in
On the other hand, what has decreased social heterogeneity is the social transformation of the class system, increasing the middle classes at the expense of the working classes and the high bourgeoisie. The attending outcome of social mobility and reduction of social barriers is an immense increase in voter volatility, as people are no longer loyal towards their social background. This has forced the political parties to change their appeal from a cleavage orientated message to issue-based platforms with a strong media appeal that change from one election to another. This has hurt especially the working-class parties, whose voters sometimes desert them for other parties, including populist ones to some extent.
The Nordic countries have been seen as prototypes for the Lipset & Rokkan (1967) theory of frozen party systems in Western Europe. Nordic politics used to be channelled through a stable and persisting pattern of social cleavages. Thus, the party system was based upon proportional representation techniques, which expressed the social cleavages in the agrarian-industrial society. The working classes had their political parties, the agrarian group its party, the middle classes their parties and the wealthy their party. Ethnicity was expressed in the Finnish party system through the Swedish People’s Party as well as in Norway in the issue of Norwegian language (“nynorsk”), whereas the aboriginal groups of Sami and Eskimos were too small or dispersed for political organisation.
Although the Nordic party systems remain multiparty systems they are no longer based upon these traditional cleavages. Profound developments both among the political parties and in the social structure have resulted in processes of dealignment as well as realignment. New parties have been formed, such as left-Socialist parties, religious parties, Green parties and populist parties. And some of the old parties dating back to the introduction of mass politics in a democratic polity have been transformed considerably, such as the Agrarian and Communist parties, becoming Centre and Socialist parties respectively. These conspicuous developments have cut the links between party support and position in the social structure, entailing a rise in gross volatility in elections in the early 2000s.
5. Parliaments
The Nordic countries have strong parliaments both on paper and in reality. Today all Nordic countries have unicameral parliaments. Denmark moved to a one-chamber system in 1953 and Sweden in 1970. The Norwegian Parliament (Stortinget) was divided into two sections (Lagtinget and Odelstinget) on legislative matters till 2009. Explicitly, their constitutions provide the national assemblies with exclusive legislative powers and formally or informally with the power to dismiss governments that lose their confidence. The political systems of the Nordic countries embrace the principle of the sovereignty of parliament, meaning that all exercise of public power must go back to law enacted in the representative assembly, which is a Westminster-model feature of Norden.
Finnish constitutionalism departs somewhat from the Scandinavian practice. It includes a presidential system of government where the powers of the President used to be truly impressive. However, it is another matter whether the presidents have managed to employ those powers. Whereas Kekkonen was stronger than both the Premier and the Cabinet over a very long period of time (1956-82), developments under Koivisto (1982-94) and Ahtisaari (1994-2000) strengthened Finnish parliamentarianism at the expense of presidential rule, at the same time as a procedure for directly electing the President was introduced in 1994. Recent constitutional changes have further reinforced the power of the Premier, as, for instance, the President can no longer dissolve parliament without such a proposal from the Premier. The first female Finnish president, Tarja Halonen (2000-2012), and her successor Sauli Niinistö elected in 2012, thus have less formal power than their predecessors. Therefore it is appropriate to classify the Finnish regime today as more parliamentarian than semi-presidential.
The amount of parliamentary activity, as well as the political significance of such activity, has increased considerably since the Second World War with all the legislation necessary for building the Nordic welfare state. As minority governments came to prevail in Denmark, Norway and Sweden, there was a major shift towards so- called committee parliamentarianism, i.e. policy-making has been negotiated in the standing committees of parliament. More and more the government needs to bargain with different parties from one policy area to the other, where the crucial decisions are hammered out in parliamentary committees. The standing committees number 26 in
Real parliamentary political power is heavily dependent upon the nature of government formation, majority governments being conducive to “Minister Caesarism”, whereas in “committee parliamentarianism” the standing committees of the National Assembly have the final responsibility for drafting the policies that parliament will vote upon. During periods of majority government, the national assemblies in reality constitute rubber- stamp bodies, approving policies that have been drawn up elsewhere, e.g. in iron triangles comprising the Cabinet, the bureaucracy and the interest groups where corporatist practices loom large.
Clearly, the typical feature of Scandinavian politics has been committee parliamentarianism, except for the periods of Social Democratic hegemony. This trend is strengthened by the tradition of a strong party cohesion at roll-call votes in Parliament. An index measuring the degree of cohesion in the mid 1990s (the rice index ranging from 0 to 100) shows scores over 96 in four of the countries, with Finland slightly deviating with a score on 88.6.
In the Nordic National Assemblies, policy-making has become more or less formalized into a semi rational policy-making structure involving the creation of a commission of inquiry whose reports are sent out for review by all concerned and then end up in parliament for committee scrutiny and final legislation. The attempt at comprehensive policy-making is combined with consultation procedures, resulting in opportunities for expressing various opinions as well as for compromise among interested parties. Starting an inquiry into matters for legislation may also be initiated by the opposition parties in parliament, by calling on the government to appoint a commission with a broadly-based representation.
The Nordic parliaments have been a vehicle for deprived groups ascending to political power to employ public policies to change society. One aspect of this is how well the opinions and the social background of the voters are represented by the MPs. Comparative data on opinion―or issue-agreement indicate that there is a variation between the Nordic countries, but with regard to the basic left-right issue dimension then there is more of agreement between voters and MPs. Two basic patterns may be identified: one elite polarized pattern where MPs on the left and on the right are more radical than their voters (
The gender dimension in the representative assembly may now be regarded as the major indicator of social representation. There has been a substantial growth in the number of female MPs in all Nordic countries. As a matter of fact, in year 2015 the Nordic countries rank among the highest with regard to female parliamentary representation worldwide. In 1950, the relative size of female representatives was 8 percent in Denmark, 9 percent in Finland, 3.5 percent in Iceland, 4.5 percent in Norway and 9.5 percent in Sweden. Around 2015 the corresponding figures had climbed to 39 percent in Denmark, 42 percent in Finland, 40 percent in Iceland, 40 percent in Norway and 45 percent in Sweden. Since 1970 there has been a steady growth in female representation, meaning that in 2015 slightly more than two in five MPs is a woman. The situation of women in Iceland once was different, and the low representation of women may have been one factor of major importance for the foundation of the Women’s Party in Iceland in the early 1980s.
6. Governments
Although the political culture in Nordic countries emphasises compromise, the goal of forming a one-party majority government has in no way lost its relevance. In Finland there is frequent resort to oversized coalitions, but in the Scandinavian states both the left and the right aims to achieve a simple majority government either by means of a minimum-winning coalition among the non-socialist parties or by means of a real majority situation in parliament for the Social Democratic parties, supported tacitly by other left-wing parties, such as the former Communist Party in Sweden. Only in Finland are there the typical so-called consociational devices like consensus governments and minority protection, whereas government formation in Scandinavia involves much of adversarial politics between the socialists and the non-socialist’s. Icelandic governments tend to be majoritarian.
Information about government formation in the four major Nordic countries is presented in Tables 10-13. Looking at the composition of government between 1945 and 2014, different kinds of government have been formed in the various Nordic States. Majority single-party governments can only be found in Norway (24 percent of the time) and in Sweden (3 percent). As a matter of fact, it has become impossible to form this kind of government today, due to the heavy party fractionalisation and multidimensional nature of the political issues. The classic examples of single-party dominance include the long period in power of the Gerhardsen Social Democratic majority government in Norway and the many years in government for the Swedish Social Democrats, ruling with a minority government, supported tacitly by one or more parties (Tables 10-13).
Majority coalitions have been formed in all the Nordic countries, but they occur very often only in Finland (86 percent) and in Iceland (96 percent). It must be emphasized, though, that oversized majority or ‘surplus’ governments are formed almost exclusively in Finland, but also occurs in Iceland. In the other countries, the majority government coalitions tend to be minimal winning. In Norway the non-socialist parties have formed majority coalition governments a couple of times (11 percent), which is also true of Denmark (5 percent) and Sweden (12 percent). The other major type of government is a Social-democratic single-party minority government, as in Sweden (68 percent), in Norway (37 percent) and Denmark (27 percent). Over time, it has become increasingly difficult to form majority governments in Scandinavia, especially in
Table 10. Governments of Denmark 1945-2015.
Note: The first party indicates the Prime minister’s affiliation.
Table 11. Governments of Finland, 1945-2015.
Note: The first party indicates the Prime minister’s affiliation.
are more and more minority coalition governments (55 percent).
One institution of major importance for the frequent use of minority governments in Nordic politics is negative parliamentarianism. Its basic rule is that governments may be formed without the explicit and positive support of a political majority in parliament. A government survives as long as it is at least tacitly tolerated, because it has to step down only when there is an intentional vote of no confidence. Actually the Schlüter government in
The overall pattern of government formation differs between the various countries, reflecting the variation in voter support for the largest party, the Social Democrats. In Norway and Sweden, the Social Democratic Party has had such a strong hold on government that people sometimes spoke of a “statist” political party. The Norwegian Social Democrats enjoyed majority support in the Stortinget in the period 1945-61, whereas the Swedish Social Democratic Party could rule as if it was a majority government from 1945 to 1976 first on the basis of government co-operation with the Agrarian Party up to 1957 and then in a minority government with the tacit support of the Communist Party, and more recently during the 1990s and the 2000s supported by either the Center Party (1994 to 1998) or the Left Party and the Green Party (1998-2006). In
Government stability has been lower in
Table 12. Governments of Norway, 1945-2015.
Note: The first party indicates the Prime minister’s affiliation.
parliamentary support hovers between 40 percent (Denmark) and 46 - 47 percent (Sweden, Norway). The chief developmental trend, however, is that government life spans have decreased in the Scandinavian countries but increased in
The pattern of ideological composition varies between the nations. Sweden and Norway have had a long tradition of single-party Social Democratic governments, covering 71 percent and 61 percent of the time between
Table 13. Governments of Sweden, 1946-2015.
Note: The first party indicates the Prime minister’s affiliation.
1945 and 2014. The Danish pattern includes both social-democratic single-party governments (27 percent) and right-wing-led governments (44 percent), while in Finland governments tend to be formed that balance the right and the left in the same cabinet (69 percent). In
Corporatist Patterns
It is impossible to talk about Nordic party government without bringing up the question of corporatism. On the one hand, inherent in the compromise culture is the fact that strong interest organisations are afforded a number of opportunities to exercise influence over policy initiation and legislative decision-making as well as policy implementation. On the other hand, since the Nordic countries are characterised by the hierarchical and encompassing nature of the interest organisations among both employees and employers, there is also strong pressure for interest consultation and interest intermediation.
Trade union density rose between 1950 and 1990 when it peaked, from 53 percent to 75 percent in
Corporatism in Nordic politics emerged from the Great Depression, when crucial system choices, or compromises, were made combining a capitalist economy with extensive state regulation and trade union involvement. The existence of strong trade unions was accepted by the employers’ associations, where industrial relations were to be managed by means of broad agreements between the interest organizations. A tripartite system of policy interaction was introduced covering the trade unions, the employers’ associations and the state.
Corporatism acquired its most characteristic features after the Second World War, when it became a cornerstone of the Scandinavian model. It involved the notion of an industrial pact between employers and employees in order to enhance economic growth by means of low wage increases resulting in low inflation. As Olson (1990) has emphasised, the Scandinavian model achieved considerable growth rates at first in Sweden and Finland and later in Norway and Denmark in the 1980s.
Each Nordic country has its own version of corporatism. Perhaps the Swedish model took social corporatism to its limits. The Swedish interest organisations were to some extent integrated with the State. Not only were they given a prominent role in the policy-making process, having the right to state their view on almost any reform proposal, but they were also partly integrated in policy implementation by virtue of their capacity to nominate members of State agencies as well as to execute public functions.
In Norway the interest groups played a large role in the promotion of an “organized democracy”, to use the words of
Olsen (1983)
. In Finland ‘structural corporatism’ grew strong in the 1960s, which resulted in a political role for the interest groups. In
1. Involvement of the interest groups in the hearings process concerning major policy reforms (“remiss”).
2. Interest groups’ participation in major policy investigations.
3. Board representation of interest groups in central government agencies.
4. Schemes for employee representation on various boards as well as for co-determination.
5. The delegation of administrative tasks to the interest group.
A conspicuous case of the last mentioned institution was the construction of the unemployment insurance funds, the Ghent system, where Denmark, Finland, Iceland and Sweden, but not Norway, have had union run unemployment insurance schemes, funded with public money but operating in accordance with public law, a system which has eroded over the last decades. Yet since the late 1980s and in the 2000s different assessments of corporatism have surfaced. Patterns of corporatist interaction are no longer sacrosanct, as they have been attacked for harbouring special interests promoting themselves at the expense of the public interest. In the wake of the economic depression of the 1990s and the economic crisis of the 2000s, the Nordic countries have attempted to remove some of their institutional sclerosis, unpacking certain corporatist schemes. Undoubtedly there has been a shift from less of corporatism to more of lobbyism when characterising the relationships between the state and the interest groups. Still it may be too early to proclaim the end of corporatism in
7. Bureaucracy, NPM and Intergovernmental Relations
Although they are unitary states, the Scandinavian countries adopted a three-tier system of government, whereas Finland and Iceland have a two-tier framework. The principle of local government autonomy has of tradition a strong standing in the Nordic countries, although there is much state regulation and state funding.
In the local government sector amalgamations have been undertaken in every country although in
During the post-war period the size of local government functions has increased, as the local government authorities are entrusted with the provision of many welfare services. Whereas the municipalities take care of education, social services and the infrastructure, the county councils are responsible for health care. In
Welfare programmes date back to the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries as the national government took steps to protect workers against the consequences of the rapid process of industrialisation and urbanisation that swept over the Nordic countries during the second half of the nineteenth century. The economic crisis of the 1930s led to sustained expansion of various aspects of the public sector, involving both the provision of welfare services and transfer payments. The real expansion of the public sector began, however, after the Second World War.
The overall growth of the public sector has been dramatic in Norden. Measured as a percentage of GDP, the Danish figures climbed from 24 percent in 1960 to 60 percent in 1993 to go down to 57 percent in 2013, in Norway from 26 percent to 55 percent and 45 percent, in Sweden from 31 percent to 71 percent and to 53 percent, whereas in Finland the expansion of the General Government started with a rise from 28 percent to 65 percent in 1993, but declined to 58 percent in 2013. Iceland went from a modest 28 percent in 1960 to 58 percent in 2008 to reach 46 percent in 2013. Considering that overall resources as measured by GDP have more than doubled during the post-war period, the increase in the capacity of the Nordic states to embark on extensive public-sector programmes involves a major change in the relations between state and society in those countries, from a historical point of view, i.e. the establishment of a mixed economy.
The Scandinavian welfare state was gradually built up on the basis of a consensualist policy style that delivered broad reform proposals backed by all except the small extremist parties. When it worked, at its best, it combined high economic growth with low unemployment and much redistribution by means of public transfer programmes. However, in the late 1970s and early 1980s the Scandinavian model began to malfunction; inflation and unemployment increased, as did the number of working days lost in strikes. The strong membership increase in several trade unions organising the public sector created more difficulties in bringing about reforms to secure economic growth. The power of distributional coalitions was strengthened along with the expansion of the public sector. During the 1980s, institutional sclerosis increased in the sense that strong policy networks could mobilise special interests to a considerable extent. The economic crises in the 1990s and the 2000s paved the way for welfare state reforms, as public sector expansion was halted and public budgets trimmed.
The Nordic welfare state comprises a set of three broad policies: extensive public resource allocation in education and health, universal transfer payments for social security and a heavy commitment to full employment, including extensive job retraining programs. The state and the local government in particular are responsible for the provision of many goods and services, final government consumption standing in 2013 at 29 percent in
At first it was possible to combine high average growth in the overall economy with steadily expanding public spending, but from the 1970s on there is a clear reduction in economic growth at the same time as the expansion of the public sector at all levels of government, but particularly the local government level, was far in excess of private-sector expansion. The Scandinavian model implies both substantial public resource allocation, providing a number of services almost free of charge, and huge social security programmes, redistributing income between various social groups. Such heavy reliance on public provision has led to a large increase in the number of public employees.
The Nordic welfare state has cherished equality as its first and foremost goal, both as equality of opportunities and equal results. Thus services were to be provided equally to all citizens, and regional and class disparities were to be equalised. When the Nordic welfare state was constructed and expanded, centralisation was the major tool, the national government laying down standards and using local government to provide the goods and services. This has had the effect that the traditional commitment to local government autonomy was weakened by the weight of state legislation and considerable allocation of central government grants to local government. However, since the beginning of the 1980s the trend has been reversed, as decentralisation has been in favour. Local governments have passed through comprehensive organisational growth processes, transforming them into huge formal organisations with large budgets and many employees.
Since the 1990s, the emphasis is upon improving efficiency in the state and the local governments. Thus cut-backs in public spending and public employment have occurred, especially at the local level. New public management (NPM) was to begin with well received in Norden, where the state, the county councils and the local governments have been interested in replacing bureaucratic organisation with tendering/bidding and internal markets. In the health care sector, such NPM reforms have been fairly comprehensive. The Danish flexicurity programs are well-known. Almost all public enterprises with a considerable total work force have been incorporated, and some privatised.
Whereas intergovernmental interaction was characterised by planning and the use of various control schemes such as detailed rule regulation in combination with earmarked grants, the strong decentralisation drive has involved a profound movement from a top-down perspective to a bottom-up approach. Framework legislation has been employed, together with block grants, augmenting discretion at the regional and local level of government, also within the state (deconcentration). The central government now only outlines the major objectives in the various policy sectors, refraining from the employment of policy instruments used earlier but underlining the relevance of the evaluation of outputs (productivity) and outcomes (effectiveness). The overall trend in intergovernmental relations is the replacement of ex ante steering mechanisms with ex post instruments such as performance evaluation in particular. Especially the costly public health care sector has experienced a number of reforms, aiming at increasing competition and choice between alternative providers while containing costs without finding an optimal format. Thus in
The process of Europeanisation has had a clear impact.
8. Institutional Reform
Considering the size of the Scandinavian welfare state, it is scarcely surprising that most reform activity has focused upon the public sector. Two chief objectives may be identified: (1) enhancement of productivity and effectiveness within State agencies and local governments, and (2) initiation of cut-back management in relation to several programmes in the social security systems. Major types of reform strategies attempted include: (1) decentralisation, and (2) privatisation, (3) new public management.
The temporal sequence between these objectives and measures is that the political reforms, particularly decentralisation, came before the resort to cut-back management and privatisation strategies. The decentralisation reform involved on the one hand deconcentration within the state, moving functions and resources from the central level to the regional and local levels of government. On the other hand, there was a strong emphasis on the values of the local government system, meaning that both the municipalities and the county councils were allowed to expand far more rapidly than the growth rate of the economy as a whole. The local governments are now the major employers of people in the Nordic countries. The reform of the Scandinavian welfare state has had a strong dose of decentralisation attempting to reduce the workload of the central government. The main exception to the emphasis upon local and regional decentralisation is the Norwegian state nationalising the hospitals in 2002, where the central government maintains a firm grip upon events, partially due to its immense revenues in the state-controlled oil sector.
The basic tenor of the debate about the pros and cons of the Scandinavian welfare state has shifted. The increasing relevance of market values in these countries, with their earlier strong socialist ambitions, was at first reflected in various institutional attempts to reform the public sector, but as the financial pressure grew along with the depression of the early 1990s it became necessary to initiate various policies of retrenchment. This applies in particular to the Swedish context, where there have been substantial cutbacks both at the central government level in the transfer programmes and at the local government level, where people have been laid off. The public sector in
The innovations in the economic reform of the public sector have comprised a number of different steps:
1. New budgetary and evaluation techniques, promoting efficiency;
2. Contracting-out or tendering/bidding;
3. Incorporation of public enterprises, i.e. transforming them into public joint-stock companies, e.g. in infrastructures such as energy and telecommunications;
4. Hiving off bureau functions to public joint-stock companies (health care);
5. User fees instead of taxation;
6. The introduction of market-type mechanisms such as internal markets as well as individual salary schemes into the state bureaucracy and especially at the local government level;
7. Privatisation proper, meaning the selling off of public property.
The reforms of the Scandinavian model of a mixed economy with a blend of market economy and large public sector that gives a high priority to distributional matters have been much inspired by the market philosophy that flows around the world with globalisation. Thus, new public management has been introduced on a large scale in some local and regional governments, especially in the health care sector. For instance, The Stockholm County Council and the “Region Skane” both employs internal markets in practically all health care supply. The transfer programmes-pensions, unemployment benefits, sickness compensation-have been restructured in accordance with ideas about incentive compatibility, as governments more and more link future benefits with past contributions or differences in salaries. Finally, the private supply of services has increased in the 2000s. Attendance in private, or independent, schools (friskoler) for the primary level (grunnskolen) was highest in Denmark around 1985 with 9 percent to have increased to 15 percent in 2013. In Sweden there has been a distinct growth from 1 percent to 13 percent during this period, whereas in the other three Nordic countries the increase has been modest from around 1 percent in 1985 to about 3 percent attendance in 2013. A similar process has taken place for the private provision of elderly care where Sweden and Finland in 2012 have an enrolment of around 17 percent whereas in Denmark and Norway the figures are around 7 - 8 percent. When the process started in Sweden in 1993 the enrolment rate was around 4 - 5 percent.
The Scandinavian model has become less monolithic, more competitive and less egalitarian. More and more of public services are contracted, either outsourcing or insourcing. And public enterprises have been fully incorporated, now being active under schemes of deregulation with some amount of private or international competition. The process of deregulation started in the 1980s (mobiles in
The major developments in 2015-16, caused by the terribly large scale civil war in Syria and Iraq, with millions of migrants coming, also from Africa where stateless societies have emerged, put additional pressure on the Nordic welfare state. It used to be renowned for its general generosity and cordial acceptance of refugees, but when numbers started to skyrocket from a few thousands up to 200 000 for Sweden, the political climate changed. In all Nordic countries, anti-foreigner or populist parties have become nfluential players with not so meagre support. The swing to the Right is undeniable (Andersen, Holmström, Honkapohja, Korkman, Söder- ström, & Vartiainen, 2007; Arter, 2008; Bergman & Strøm (eds), 2011; Bergmann, 2014; Bergqvist (ed), (1999); Gylfason, Holmström, Korkman, Söderström, & Vihriälä, 2010; Heidar (ed), 2004; Hilson, 2008; Ingebritsen, 2006; Jenssen, Pesonen, & Gilljam (eds), 1998; Lindwall, 2012) .
9. Conclusion
The Scandinavian model outlined a distinct set of political institutions that made Nordic politics different from both Anglo-Saxon practices and Continental European realities. It combined adversarial politics with consensus institutions, the latter including anything from patterns of consultation and negotiation in parliament to corporatist policy concentration. Compromise politics between socialists and non-socialists resulted in a strong policy commitment to the welfare state without parallel elsewhere (Pontusson, 2011; Raunio & Tiilikainen, 2003; Sejersted, 2011) .
Yet Scandinavian political institutions were not working as they used to when the reputation of this institutional model was at its peak, in the 1970s and 1980s. There was lower consensus between the labour market organizations. The public sector had been transformed by structural reform, underlining market incentives and contracting, at a time when the major process of public-sector growth was halted. Besides the drive for more efficiency in public services, cutback strategies had been implemented, particularly in Sweden and Finland. The Scandinavian model had been transformed in several ways: less corporatism, more choice and competition, as well as less collectivism and more personal freedom.
The reforms of the 1990s and early 2000s stemmed from recognition that it was not easy to combine the two basic values of the Scandinavian welfare state-efficiency and equality. Some data indicated profound public sector-productivity problems, and the comprehensive and generous transfer programmes were hardly incentive compatible with the presuppositions of an advanced open market economy. There had increasingly been a search for efficiency-enhancing reforms and retrenchment policies that trimmed the social security systems and workfare policies. The question of membership in the European Union and adherence to the Euro raised the same type of confrontation in Finland, Norway and Sweden, where adherents underlined the economic benefits whereas opponents feared the negative regional consequences.
A most conspicuous change in Nordic politics is the increase in electoral volatility, although relatively low in a European context. The processes of dealignment and realignment have resulted in party system transformation, including the phenomenon of new politics, as well as in governmental instability, which makes policy-making more complicated. The typical compromise institutions now involve more unpredictability and strategic behaviour. Scandinavian exceptionalism is waning at the same time as Norden is becoming increasingly integrated into
Yet we have noted a revival of the “Nordic model” in the 2010s. Nordic exceptionalism is to be found with respect to the following combination of traits: the electoral system of proportional representation; party systems with a multidimensional issue pattern; parliamentary behaviour supported by strong committees; the patterns of coalition formation prone to minority cabinets and oversized cabinets; state structure including local government autonomy and the Ombudsman; as well as corporatist policy-making accompanied with a decreasing but still high trade union density. Nevertheless,
Nordic societies like capitalist democracies in Western Europe today are very different from the fully blown industrial democracies after the Second World War to such an extent that one is inclined to agree with the wellknown French social scientist Touraine (2013) when he speaks of the change from a Durkheimian (“stru- cture”) to a Weberian world (“actor”) in his La fin des societes. The end of society is a thesis that aims to cover the emancipation of the ego from social and moral constraints, i.e. rules and institutions that have dominated men and women, often for a long time period. The post-modern society would, according to Touraine, be less focussed upon social groups and more concentrated upon the individual actor. He admits himself that his long-time preference for French classic Durkheim, emphasizing “collective consciousness” and its implications for social action has to be abandoned in favour of a renewed appreciation of Weber, who wrote: “Jede denkende Besinnung auf die letzten Elemente sinnvoller menschlichen Handelns is zunacht gebunden an die Kategorien ‘Zweck’ und “Mittel” (Weber, 1922, 1985: p. 214) . This starting-point?the Ich of the actor?is more promising that the Uns of the group, when enquiring into the post-modern society today, where persons decide what to do but institutions have declined, in religion, morals, economics and politics?this is the Touraine thesis, highly relevant not only for France but also Scandinavia and Finland, whose exceptionalism is gone by now, political instability replacing stability and the “frozen party system” (Rokkan, 1970).
Acknowledgements
My debt to Svante Ersson and his Umea data archive is beyond recognition. He is a master of quantitative empirical enquiry compartively
Cite this paper
Jan Erik Lane, (2016) The Nordic Countries: From the Rokkan Model (“uns”) to the Touraine Model (“ich”). Open Journal of Political Science,06,284-309. doi: 10.4236/ojps.2016.63026
References
- 1. Arter, D. (2008). Scandinavian Politics Today (2nd ed.) Manchester: Manchester University Press.
- 2. Bergman, T., & Strom, K. (eds) (2011). The Madisonian Turn: Political Parties and Parliamentary Democracy in Nordic Europe. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.
- 3. Bergmann, E. (2014). Iceland and the International Financial Crisis: Boom, Bust and Recovery. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/9781137332004
- 4. Bergqvist, C. (ed) (1999). Equal Democracies?: Gender and Politics in the Nordic Countries. Oslo: Scandinavian University Press.
- 5. Heidar, K. (ed) (2004). Nordic Politics: Comparative Perspectives. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.
- 6. Hilson, M. (2008). The Nordic Model: Scandinavia Since 1945. London: Reaktion Books.
- 7. Ingebritsen, C. (2006). Scandinavia in World Politics. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield.
- 8. Jenssen, A. T., Pesonen, P., & Gilljam, M. (eds) (1998). To Join or Not to Join: Three Nordic Referendums on Membership in the European Union. Oslo: Scandinavian University Press.
- 9. Lindwall, J. (2012). Politics and Policies in Two Economic Crises: The Nordic Countries. In N. Bermeo & J. Pontusson (Eds.), Coping with the Crisis: Government Reactions to the Great Recession. New York: Russell Sage.
- 10. Lipset, S. M., & Rokkan, S. (1967). Cleavage Structures, Party Systems and Voter Alignments: An Introduction. In S. M. Lipset & S. Rokkan (Eds.), Party Systems and Voter Alignments: Cross-National Perspectives. New York: Free Press.
- 11. Olsen, J. P. (1983). Organized Democracy: Political Institutions in a Welfare State: The Case of Norway. Bergen: Universitetsforlaget.
- 12. Olson, M. (1990). How Bright Are the Northern Lights? Some Questions about Sweden. Lund: Lund University Press.
- 13. Pontusson, J. (2011). Once Again a Model: Nordic Social Democracy in a Globalized World. In J. Cronin, G. Ross, & J. Shoch (Eds.), What’s Left of the Left: Democrats and Social Democrats in Challenging Times. Durham: Duke University Press. http://dx.doi.org/10.1215/9780822394518-004
- 14. Raunio, T., & Tiilikainen, T. (2003). Finland in the European Union. London: Frank Cass.
- 15. Sejersted, F. (2011). The Age of Social Democracy: Norway and Sweden in the Twentieth Century. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
- 16. The Economist (2013) The Nordic Countries: The Next Supermodel.
- 17. Touraine, A. (2013). La fin de la societe. Paris: Seuil.
- 18. Weber, M. (1922, 1985). Gesammelte Aufsaetze zur Wissenschaftslehre. Tuebingen: J.C. Mohe.
- 19. Rokkan, S. (1970). Citizens, Elections and Parties. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget (Reprinted 2009 by the ECPR, Univ of Essex).