Theoretical Economics Letters
Vol.3 No.1(2013), Article ID:28174,2 pages DOI:10.4236/tel.2013.31012

Kalai-Smorodinsky Bargaining Solution and Alternating Offers Game

Yoichi Nishihara

Hiroshima University, Hiroshima, Japan

Email: nishihara@hiroshima-u.ac.jp

Received December 7, 2012; revised January 8, 2013; accepted February 10, 2013

Keywords: Bargaining Solution; Alternating Offers Game; Breakdown

ABSTRACT

This article presents an alternating offers game that supports a Kalai-Smorodinsky bargaining solution (KSS). It is well known that a solution to an alternating offers game has a breakdown point equivalent to a status quo that converges to its Nash bargaining solution because the probability of breakdown becomes negligible, whereas we show that a KSS is obtained if a breakdown gives everything to the player who rejects. The former option, which is adopted by many application papers may be suitable for ex ante production. However, the latter option should be more appropriate for ex post production, because players do not need to be concerned with cooperation.

1. Introduction

Kalai and Smorodinsky [1] proposed an axiomatic bargaining solution, known as the Kalai-Smorodinsky bargaining solution (KSS), that differs from the one pioneered by Nash [2], which imposed monotonicity instead of independence to irrelevant alternatives. Shaked and Sutton [3] connected a Nash bargaining solution with an alternating offers game originated by Rubinstein [4], whereas the relationship between a KSS and an alternating offers game has not yet been clarified. Therefore, this study investigates a KSS for this type of game.

In connection with this study, it is interesting to note that monotonicity is substantially incompatible with the irrelevance of independent alternatives [5]. In addition to our consideration of axiomatic approaches and alternating offers games, it may be important to consider other dimensions such as demand games [6,7] and implementations [8,9]. Extensions of KSS for asymmetry [10], endogenous disagreement [11] and non-convex bargaining sets [12] could be examined in each contrasting dimension.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 constructs an alternating offers game, Section 3 finds an equilibrium equivalent to a KSS, and Section 4 concludes this paper.

2. Model

Two players, 1 and 2, alternately offer their partitions on a strictly convex bargaining set where the frontier is strictly decreasing. Without any loss of generality, such a set is characterized by, where,

, and, a continuous function is assumed. The game proceeds as follows. Player 1 offers and if player 2 accepts, the game ends with the payoff vector. If player 2 rejects the offer, the bargain breaks off with a probability. In that case, the game ends with. If it continues, the players’ positions are exchanged. Thusan offer is and the payoff vectors are, respectively, if the offer is accepted and if the bargain breaks, while the opportunity to offer reverts to player 1 if the game continues.

3. Analysis

This section shows that stationary perfect equilibria in the game converge to the KSS where intersects the straight line from the origin (Figure 1), where the slope is. No equilibrium consists of repetitive refusalswhich expects the payoff vector, because the bargaining set is strictly convex.

First, the existence of stationary equilibria is assured.

Proposition 1. There is a stationary equilibrium.

Proof. In stationary equilibria, the one shot deviation properties

(1)

Figure 1. Allocations on a frontier.

(2)

must be satisfied. Let and . Because

and, there is a stationary solution due to continuity. □

Next, the uniqueness of the convergence point is stated. This allocation is the same as that of the KSS.

Proposition 2. Any stationary equilibrium converges on the KSS as.

Proof. When p → 0 in Equations (1) and (2), and. Thus, it is sufficient to show that

owing to the squeeze theorem.

Suppose that

then,

as. This contradicts and it is similar for player 2. □

To eliminate the strictness on the convexity and decrease in, we can impose continuity on a solution with sequences inside and outside the frontiers.

4. Conclusion

The above bargain can be broken off with polar allocations whenever a player rejects an offer, such as when an arbiter abandons a wilful player who offers unreasonably and determines that the availability of resources is not settled during a dispute. This implies that each player can only individually use the resources. This type of bargain is concerning during the sharing of ex post production. By contrast, a Nash bargaining solution is supported when both parties receive nothing following a breakdown. Cooperation is needed to ensure gain, so this type of bargain is likely to arise during ex ante production. Thus, the difference between the two solution concepts may be due to the timing, particularly during competition for resources.

REFERENCES

  1. E. Kalai and M. Smorodinsky, “Other Solutions to Nash’s Bargaining Problem,” Econometrica, Vol. 43, No. 3, 1975, pp. 513-518. doi:10.2307/1914280
  2. J. Nash, “Two-Person Cooperative Games,” Econometrica, Vol. 21, No. 1, 1953, pp. 128-140. doi:10.2307/1906951
  3. A. Shaked and J. Sutton, “Involuntary Unemployment as a Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model,” Econometrica, Vol. 52, No. 6, 1984, pp. 1351-1364. doi:10.2307/1913509
  4. A. Rubinstein, “Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model,” Econometrica, Vol. 50, No. 1, 1982, pp. 97-109. doi:10.2307/1912531
  5. S. Rachmilevitch, “Cooperative Bargaining: Independence and Monotonicity Imply Disagreement,” Economics Letters, Vol. 118, No. 1, 2013, pp. 240-242. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2012.10.024
  6. J. Nash, “The Bargaining Problem,” Econometrica, Vol. 18, No. 2, 1950, pp. 155-162. doi:10.2307/1907266
  7. N. Anbarci and J. H. Boyd III, “Nash Demand Game and the Kalai-Smorodinsky Solution,” Games and Economic Behavior, Vol. 71, No. 1, 2011, pp. 14-22. doi:10.1016/j.geb.2010.07.009
  8. J. V. Howard, “A Social Choice Rule and Its Implementation in Perfect Equilibrium,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 56, No. 1, 1992, pp. 142-159. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(92)90073-Q
  9. H. Moulin, “Implementing the Kalai-Smorodinsky Bargaining Solution,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 33, No. 1, 1984, pp. 32-45. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(84)90038-3
  10. J. Dubra, “An Asymmetric Kalai-Smorodinsky Solution,” Economics Letters, Vol. 73, No. 2, 2001, pp. 131- 136. doi:10.1016/S0165-1765(01)00426-8
  11. I. Bozbay, F. Dietrich and H. Peters, “Bargaining with Endogenous Disagreement: The Extended Kalai-Smorodinsky Solution,” Games and Economic Behavior, Vol. 74, No. 1, 2012, pp. 407-417. doi:10.1016/j.geb.2011.06.007
  12. T. Anant, B. Mukherji and K. Basu, “Bargaining without Convexity: Generalizing the Kalai-Smorodinsky Solution,” Economics Letters, Vol. 30, No. 2, 1990, pp. 115- 119. doi:10.1016/0165-1765(90)90155-T