Journal of Mathematical Finance
Vol.3 No.2(2013), Article ID:31789,5 pages DOI:10.4236/jmf.2013.32023
Semimartingale Property and Its Connections to Arbitrage*
School of Mathematical Science, Anhui University, Hefei, China
Email: ssallieu@yahoo.com, maojunjun@ahu.edu.cn, yaodengbao@126.com
Copyright © 2013 Sallieu Kabay Samura et al. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Received January 27, 2013; revised March 25, 2013; accepted April 11, 2013
Keywords: Bichteler-Dellaccherie Theorem; Doob-Meyer Decomposition; Semi-Martingales; Arbitrage; Komlos Lemma
ABSTRACT
In this paper, we prove the celebrated Bichteler-Dellaccherie Theorem which states that the class of stochastic processes X allowing for a useful integration theory consists precisely of those processes which can be written in the form X = X0 + M + A, where M0 = A0 = 0, M is a local martingale, and A is of finite variation process. We obtain this decomposition rather direct form an elementary discrete-time Doob-Meyer decomposition. By moving to convex combination we obtain a direct continuous time decomposition, which then yield the desired decomposition. We also obtain a characterization of semi-martingales in terms of a variant no free lunch with vanishing risk.
1. Introduction
In this paper, is assumed to be a filtered probability space where
is a filtration satisfying
for all
, the usual condition of right continuity and completeness. The random movement of
risky assets in the market is modeled via cadlag, nonnegative stochastic processes
, where
. We assume that all wealth processes are discounted by another special asset which is considered a baseline. In the market described above, economic agents can trade in order to reallocate their wealth.
Consider a simple predictable process
.
where, and for all
,
is a finite stopping time and
is
-measurable.
Each,
, is an instance when some give economic agent may trade in the market, then,
is the number of unit from the ith risky assets that the agent will hold in the trading interval
. This form of trading is called simple, as it comprises of finite number of buy-and-hold strategies, in contrast to continuous trading where one is able to change the position of the assets in a continuous fashion. The last form of trading is only theoretical value, since it cannot be implemented in reality, even if one ignores market frictions.
Starting from initial capital and following the strategy described by the simple predictable process
, the agent’s discounted process is given by
.
where,
are a.s. finite stoping times with respect to
and the
are
-measurable real random variables. Note that the trader is allowed to trade on an infinite time horizon, because we do not restrict to bounded stoping times for the re-allocation of the capital. Of course trading on a finite time horizon [0, T] is covered by switching to the process
.
Theorem 1.1. [1,2] A real valued, cadlag, adapted process the following are equivalent:
1) X is a good integrator.
2) X may be decomposed as, where
is a local martingale and
is an adapted process of finite variation.
Defination 1.1. [1,3] A real valued, cadlag, adapted process allows for A Free Lunch With Vanishing Risk for simple integrands if there is a sequence
of simple integrands such that for
,
.
and
In contrast, X therefore admits No Free Lunch With Vanishing Risk (NFLVR) for simple integrands if for every sequence satisfying (VR) we have
(NFL) in probability.
A free lunch with vanishing risk (FLVR) for simple integrands indicates that S allows for a sequence of trading schemes, each
involving only finitely many rebalancing of the portfolio, such that the losses tend to Zero in the sense that of (VR) ,while the terminal gains (FL) remain substantial as n goes to infinity. It is important to note that the condition (VR) of vanishing risk pertains the maximal losses of the trading strategy
during the entire interval [0,T]: if the left hand side of (VR) equals
this implies that, with probability one, the strategy
never, i.e. for not
, cause an accumulated loss of more than
.
Resently, it has been argued that existence of an Equivalent Martingale Measure(EMM) is not necessary for viability of the market; to see this effect, see [4-6]. In [7], the concept of strictly positive supermartingale deflator which is weaker than the existence of an EMM, that allows for consistent theory to be developed.In this paper, we investigate the relation between the no free lunch with vanishing risk property for simple integands and the semimartingale property.
Theorem 1.2. [1,8] Let be a real-valued, cadlag, locally bounded process based on and adepted to a filtered probability space
. If S satisfies the condition of no free lunch with vanishing risk (NFLVR) for simple integrands then S is a semimartingale.
Theorem 1.3. For a locally bounded, adopted, cadlag process X the following are equivalent 1) X satisfies NFLVR + LI(little Investment)
2) X is a classical semimartingale.
Theorem 1.4. For an adapted cadlag process X the following are equivalent.
1) For all sequences of simple predictable processesa)
b)
together imply in probability.
2) X is a classical semimartingale.
Proposition 1.5. Let be cadlag and adapted, with X0 and such that
and X satisfies NFLVR + LI For all
there is
and a sequence of stopping times
such that, for all n 1)
takes values in
.
2).
3) The stopped processes and
satisfyfor all n,
and
Lemma 1.6. Under the assumptions as in the proposition above with
the sequence
is bounded in probability.
Proof. For all n, let
a simple predictable process, then since
since X satisfies NFLVR + LI, is bounded in
.
For define a sequence of stopping times
.
Given there is
such that
Lemma 1.7. Under the same assumptions as in Proposition 1.5 the stopped martingales satisfy
.
Proof. For and
, since the
are predictable and the
are martingales,
we write as a telescoping series and simplifying to get
Lemma 1.8. Let
.
Under the assumption of Proposition 1.5 the sequence is bounded in probability.
Proof. Assume for contradiction that is not bounded in probability. Then there is
such that for all k there is
such that
For
define
and
.
Then and
and at time t = 1 we have
.
But the second summand is bounded in L2, so we conclude that is not bounded in probability.
We defined a sequence of stopping times
.
Because
by Doob’s sub-martingale in-equality,(see [9,10])
is bounded in probability. Therefore there is
such that
. Note that
is uniformly bounded below by
. We claim
is not bounded in probability. Indeed, for any n and any k,
Since, the probability of the other event is at least
. This gives the desired contradiction because it is now easy to construct a FLVR + LI.
Proof of Proposition 1.5: Defined a sequence of stopping times
.
By Lemma 1.8 there is c2 such that. Take
and
Lemma 1.9. [11]. Let be measurable functions, where f is left continuous and takes finitely many values. Say
. Define
where is the biggest of the k such that Xk less than or equal to t. Then for all partition
,
Proposition 2.0. Let be cadlag and adopted, with
and such that
and X satisfies NFLVR + LI. For all
there is C and a
valued stopping time
such that
and sequence
and
of continuous time cadlag processes such that for all n1)
2)
3) is a martingale with
4)
Proof. Let be given. Let C,
,
, and
be as in proposition 1.5. Extended
and
to all
by defining
and
. Not that the extended
is no longer predictable, and currently we only have control of the total variation of
over
, i.e.
Notice that, for,
From this and it follow that
, so
. How do we fine the limit of the sequence of stopping times
? The trick is to define
, a simple predicator process, and note that stopping at
is like integrating Rn, i.e.
and
. We have that
.
Apply Komlos’ Lemma to obtain convex weights such that
a.s as By the dominated convergence theorem,
. Observe that
Define. Each
is left continuous, decreasing process. In particular,
, so we can divide by this quantity. We claim that
. In deed, on the event
,
so
Define new processes. Then
and
. Thus we define Mn and An by
The total variation of over
is bounded by 3. By Lemma 1.9,
That follows from the fact that
. To finish the proof, we show that there is a subsequence
such that
satisfies
. We know
because
. Since
a.s there is a subsequence such that
. Finally,
Therefore,
and
have the desired properties.
Proof of the Main Theorems Proof of Theorem 1.3. We may assume the hypothesis of proposition. Let and take C,
,
,
as in proposition. Apply komlos lemma to find convex weights
such that
for all, where the convergence is a.s. For all n,
so the total variation of A over D is bounded by C. Further, we have
. A is a cadlag on D, so define it on all of [0,1] to make it cadlag. M is
martingale so it has a cadlag modification. Since
and
was arbitrary, and the class of classical semimartingales is local, X must be a classical semimartingale.
Proof of Theorem 1.4. We no longer assume that X is locally bounded. The trick is to leverage the result for locally bounded processes by subtracting the big jump from X. Assume without loss of generality that and defined
. Then X = X − J is an adopted, cadlag locally bounded process. We will show that theorem 1.4 for X implies NFLVR + LI for X, so that we may apply theorem 1.3 to X. Then since J is finite variation, this will then imply X is a classical semimartingale .
Suppose are such that
and
. We need to prove that
in probability . First we will show that
.
by the assumptions on
By (1), in probability. Since
in probability, we conclude that
in probability. Therefore X satisfies NFLVR + LI.
REFERENCES
- F. Delbaen and W. Schachermayer, “A General Version of the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing,” Mathematische Annalen, Vol. 300 No. 3, 1994, pp.463-520. doi:10.1007/BF01450498
- P. E. Protter, “Stochastic Integration and Differential Equation,” 2nd Edition, Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 2004.
- M. Beiglblock, W. Schachermayer and B. Veliyev, “A Direct Proof of the Bichteler-Dellacherie Theorem and Connections to Arbitrage,” 2010.
- M. Loewenstein and G. A. Willard, “Local Martingales, Arbitrage, and Viability Free Snacks and Cheap Thrills,” Economic Theory, Vol. 16, No. 1, 2000, pp.135-161. doi:10.1007/s001990050330
- E. Platen, “Arbitrage in Continueous Complete Markets,” Advances in Applied Probability, Vol. 34, No. 3, 2002, pp.540-558. doi:10.1239/aap/1033662165
- R. Fernholz, I. Karatzas and C. Kardaras, “Diversity and Relative Arbitrage in Equity Markets,” Finance and Stochastics, Vol. 9, No. 1, 2005, pp.1-27. doi:10.1007/s00780-004-0129-4
- C. Kardaras and E. Platen, “On the Semimartingale Property of Discounted Asset-Price Processes,” Stochastic Processes and Their Applications, Vol. 121, 2011, pp. 2678-2691.
- F. Delbaen and W. Schachermayer, “Arbitrage and Free Lunch with Bounded Risk for Unbounded Continuous Processes,” Mathematical Finance, Vol. 4, No. 4, 1994, pp. 343-348. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9965.1994.tb00063.x
- D. Williams, “Probability with Martingales,” Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1991. doi:10.1017/CBO9780511813658
- I. Karatzas and S. E. Shrve, “Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus of Graduate Text in Mathematics,” 2nd Edition, Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 1991.
- J. Komlos, “A generalization of problem of Steinhaus,” Acta Mathematica Academiae Scientiarum Hungarica, Vol. 18, No. 1-2, 1967, pp. 217-229. doi:10.1007/BF02020976
NOTES
*Supported by the NNSF of China (11171001), HSSPF of the Ministry of Education of China (10YJA910005), Talents youth Fund of Anhui Province Universities (2010SQRL016ZD), Academic Innovation Team of Anhui University (KJTD001B) and Youth Science Research Fund of Anhui University (2009QN011A).