Applied Mathematics
Vol.5 No.2(2014), Article ID:42167,22 pages DOI:10.4236/am.2014.52028

Optimal Consumption under Uncertainties: Random Horizon Stochastic Dynamic Roy’s Identity and Slutsky Equation

David W. K. Yeung1,2

1Center of Game Theory, St Petersburg State University, St Petersburg, Russia

2SRS Consortium for Advanced Study in Cooperative Dynamic Games, Shue Yan University, Hong Kong, China

Email: dwkyeung@hksyu.edu

Received June 17, 2013; revised July 17, 2013; accepted July 24, 2013

ABSTRACT

This paper extends Slutsky’s classic work on consumer theory to a random horizon stochastic dynamic framework in which the consumer has an inter-temporal planning horizon with uncertainties in future incomes and life span. Utility maximization leading to a set of ordinary wealth-dependent demand functions is performed. A dual problem is set up to derive the wealth compensated demand functions. This represents the first time that wealth-dependent ordinary demand functions and wealth compensated demand functions are obtained under these uncertainties. The corresponding Roy’s identity relationships and a set of random horizon stochastic dynamic Slutsky equations are then derived. The extension incorporates realistic characteristics in consumer theory and advances the conventional microeconomic study on consumption to a more realistic optimal control framework.

Keywords:Optimal Consumption; Uncertain Inter-Temporal Budget; Stochastic Dynamic Programming; Slutsky Equation

1. Introduction

In a ground-breaking analysis by Slutsky [1], the foundation for rigorous analysis of optimal consumption decision was laid. This masterpiece which brought mathematical rigor to demand analysis is undisputedly an integral part of contemporary mainstream economics. It allows the problem of the consumer to be analyzed in terms of a utility maximization problem subject to a budget constraint. A dual problem to the utility maximization problem is the minimization of the budget (income) subject to maintaining the utility level achieved before. In particular, the effect of a price change on the demand of goods can be decomposed into tractable terms from the primal and dual problems yielding significant economic implications. This prominent contribution in consumer theory, known as the Slutsky equation, was christened by John Hicks as the “Fundamental Equation of Value Theory”. An important economic implication of the Slutsky equation is the now famous Hicksian decomposition which separates the effect of a change in price on demand into a pure substitution effect and an income effect. The papers [2-7] propagated Slutsky’s classic work. Yeung [8] extends Slutsky’s work to a dynamic framework in which the consumer has a T-period life span with future incomes being uncertain.

Another milestone in consumer theory is the Roy’s identity [9] which provides an often invoked mathematical result in consumer theory. The identity is also instrumental to prove the Slutsky equation. In this paper, uncertainties in future incomes and the consumer’s life span are incorporated to reflect the realities in consumer choice. In particular, optimal consumption choice under these two types of uncertainties is examined. Intertemporal wealth-dependent ordinary demand functions and wealth compensated demand functions are obtained. Two of the most crucial foundations in consumer theory—Roy’s identity and Slutsky equation—are derived in a random horizon stochastic dynamic framework.

The paper is organized as follows. We first present a model of utility maximization by a consumer with an uncertain life span and an uncertain inter-temporal budget in Section 2. In Section 3, a set of wealth-dependent ordinary demands is characterized. The Roy’s identity in a random horizon stochastic dynamic framework is derived in Section 4. The dual problem is formulated in Section 5 and wealth compensated demand functions are obtained. Stochastic dynamic Slutsky equations for the consumer with an uncertain life span are formulated in Section 6. An illustration with explicit utility functions is given in Section 7. Section 8 concludes the paper.

2. Utility Maximization under Random Life Span and Uncertain Income

Consider the case of a consumer whose life-span involves periods where is a random variable with range and corresponding probabilities. Conditional upon the reaching of period, the probability of the consumer’s life-span would last up to periods becomes respectively

(1)

We use to denote the quantities of goods consumed and the corresponding prices in period. The consumer maximizes his expected inter-temporal utility

, (2)

subject to the budget constraint characterized by the wealth dynamics

(3)

where is the interest rate; is the random income that the consumer will receive in period; and, for, is a set of statistically independent random variables, and is the expectation operation with respect to the statistics of. The random variable has a non-negative range with corresponding probabilities.

Again, the time preference factor is embodied in the utility function the random variable has a value of zero with probability 1 because the consumer will receive no income in period. Moreover, under the axiom of non-satiation, the consumer will spend all his wealth in the last period of his life span and therefore. The problem (2)-(3) is a discrete-time stochastic control problem (see [10,11]).

Now consider the case when the consumer has lived to period and his wealth is. The consumer problem can formulized as the maximization of the payoff:

, (4)

subject to the budget constraint characterized by the wealth dynamics

(5)

In a stochastic dynamic framework, strategy space with state-dependent property has to be considered. In particular, a pre-specified class of mapping with the property

, for, is the strategy space and each of its elements is a admissible strategy. We define the value function and the set of strategies which provides an optimal consumption solution as follows:

(6)

for.

In particular, reflects the expected inter-temporal utility that the consumer will obtain from period to the end of his life span. Following the analysis of Yeung and Petrosyan [12,13] one can derive an optimal solution to the random-horizon consumer problem (2)-(3) as follows:

Theorem 2.1. A set of consumption strategies provides an optimal solution to the random horizon consumer problem (2)-(3) if there exist functions, for, such that the following recursive relations are satisfied:

and,

(7)

Proof. Following Bellman’s [14] technique of dynamic programming we begin with the last period/period. By definition, the utility of the consumer at period and therefore.

We first consider the case when the consumer survives in the last period and the state. The problem then becomes

(8)

subject to

. (9)

Since with probability 1, and, the problem in (8)-(9) can be expressed as the second equation in Theorem 2.1.

Now consider the problem in period. Invoking the probabilities that the consumer can live up to periods and, the problem in period can be expressed as maximizing

(10)

subject to

(11)

If the value function exists, the problem (10)-(11) can be expressed as a single period problem:

(12)

Now consider the problem in period. Following the analysis above, the problem in period becomes the maximization of the expected payoff

(13)

subject to

(14)

Note that in (13) the term

(15)

gives the expected intertemporal utility to be maximized in period. If the value function exists, the problem (13)-(14) can be formulated as a single period problem which maximizes the expected payoff

(16)

If exists, we have the third set of equations in Theorem 2.1. Hence Theorem 2.1 follows. ■

The stochastic optimal state trajectory derived from Theorem 2.1 is characterized by:

We use to denote the set which contains all possible values of wealth at period along the optimal trajectory generated by Theorem 2.1.

3. Wealth-Dependent Ordinary Demand under Uncertain Life Span and Income

In this section, we consider the primal problem of deriving wealth-dependent ordinary demand functions in which the consumer maximizes his inter-temporal expected utility subject to uncertain inter-temporal budget and life span. Following the analysis in [8] we first consider the case when the consumer survives in the last period, that is period. Let denote the consumer’s wealth in period. Given that and, to exhaust all the wealth in this period,. Hence the consumer faces the problem

(17)

Problem (17) is a standard single period utility maximization problem. Setting up the corresponding Lagrange problem and performing the relevant maximization one obtains a set of first order conditions. It is well-known (see [15]) that if the set of first order conditions satisfies the implicit function theorem, one can obtain the ordinary demand as explicit functions of the parameters and, that is:

(18)

One can readily observe that corresponds to the optimal consumption strategies in Theorem 2.1. Substituting (18) into (17) yields the indirect utility function in period as

. Invoking the definition in Equation (6), equals the function

in Theorem 2.1.

Now consider the case when the consumer survives in the second last period. If wealth equals in this period, the problem in concern becomes

subject to the inter-temporal budget

(19)

Let denote the wealth at period if has occurred.

Using the indirect utility function, the problem facing the consumer in period can be expressed as a single-period problem:

(20)

First order condition for a maximizing solution yields

(21)

Again, with the implicit function holding, (21) can be solved to yield the ordinary demands in period

as, for. Substituting into (20) yields the inter-temporal indirect utility function. Invoking Equation (6) and Theorem 2.1,

corresponds to.

Repeating the analysis for periods to 1 yields the consumer problem at period as

(22)

where, , and is the short form for the vector.

First order condition for a maximizing solution to the problems in (22) can be obtained as:

(23)

for and.

Note also the condition that in period, good will be consumed up the point where marginal utility of consumption equals times the expected marginal utility of wealth

.

In particular, the expected marginal utility of wealth takes into consideration the random future income and the probability of the consumer surviving in period. Solving (23) yields the ordinary demands in period as:

(24)

After solving the primal consumer problem which maximizes expected utility subject to an uncertain intertemporal budget and life span, we proceed to derive the Roy’s identity result in a random horizon stochastic dynamic framework.

4. Random Horizon Stochastic Dynamic Roy’s Identity

In this section we derive the random horizon version of the stochastic dynamic Roy’s Identity. Invoking (23) we obtain the identity

(25)

Differentiating the inter-temporal indirect utility function in (25) with respect to:

(26)

where, and.

Invoking the first order conditions in (23) the term inside the curly brackets vanishes, condition (26)then becomes:

(27)

The effect of a change in initial wealth on the maximized utility can be obtained by differentiating in (25) with respect to:

(28)

Again, invoking the first order conditions in (23), the term inside the curly brackets vanishes, condition (28) then becomes:

(29)

Dividing the right-hand-side of (27) by the right-hand-side of (29) yields:

(30)

Condition (30) provides a random horizon stochastic dynamic version of the Roy’s Identity involving a change in current prices.

Then we consider deriving the random horizon stochastic dynamic Roy’s Identity for a change in prices in current and future periods.

Theorem 4.1. Random Horizon Stochastic Dynamic Roy’s Identity

(31)

(32)

for, andwhere

(33)

Proof. See Appendix A of this Chapter. ■

Theorem 4.1 gives the random horizon stochastic dynamic Roy’s identity. Invoking (73) in the proof of Theorem 4.1 in Appendix A, an alternative form of the random horizon stochastic dynamic Roy’s identity can be expressed as:

(34)

for, , and.

5. Duality and Wealth Compensated Demand

In this section, we invoke the duality principle in consumer theory to construct wealth compensated demand functions under an uncertain inter-temporal budget and a random life span by considering the dual problem of minimizing expenditure covered by the current wealth subject to maintaining the level of utility achieved in the primal problem. Again, following the analysis in [8] we first consider the last period in which is the consumer’s wealth if he survives in the period. Since wealth equals income in this period, to derive the compensated demand we follow the standard single period consumer problem of

subject to achieving the level of utility

(35)

Setting the corresponding Lagrange function and performing the minimization operation yields a set of first order conditions. With the implicit function theorem holding for the first order conditions one can obtain the wealth (income) compensated demand functions as

(36)

Substituting (36) into (35) yields the wealth-expenditure function.

Now we proceed to period and let wealth in this period be. To obtain the wealth compensated demand function in period we consider the problem of minimizing expenditure covered by current wealth in the period to bring about the expected inter-temporal utility from the primal problem. However, wealth in period does not only cover consumption expenditure in the period but also part of the consumption expenditure in period. To delineate expenditures attributed to wealth in period we first invoke the dynamical Equation (3) and express as:

. (37)

Using the wealth expenditure function in period and taking expectation over the random variable in (37) one can obtain a crucial identity relating wealth to current and expected future expenditures attributable to wealth as:

(38)

Using (38) the consumer’s dual problem in period can be formulated as minimizing wealth expenditure

(39)

with respect to subject to the constraint

(40)

Since is a set of wealth compensated demands that leads to the level of utilityso equals.

Invoking

the constraint (40) can be expressed as:

Setting the Lagrange function and performing the relevant optimization operation (similar to the analysis in [8]) yields a set of first order conditions. With the implicit function theorem holding, the wealth compensated demand functions can be obtained as:

(41)

Substituting the wealth compensated demand functions in (41) into (39) yields the wealth-expenditure function in period:

(42)

Now we proceed to period and let wealth be in the period. Again using (3)

we can express wealth in period as. Taking expectations over the random variable and invoking the wealth expenditure functions in period, one can obtain the identity

(43)

where is the short form for.

The consumer’s wealth expenditure minimization problem can be expressed as:

(44)

subject to

(45)

for and.

Setting up the Lagrange function and deriving the first order conditions one can obtain the wealth compensated demand functions (with the implicit function theorem holding) as, for

, and.

Similarly, the wealth-expenditure function can be obtained as:

(46)

The wealth compensation demand functions and wealth-expenditure functions derived in this section represent the dual results of the primal problem in Section 3.

6. Random Horizon Stochastic Dynamic Slutsky Equations

In this section, we derive the Slutsky equations under an uncertain inter-temporal budget and random horizon.

Invoking the duality results in Section 3 and Section 5 we have, and

and, for and and.

Substituting by into the wealth-dependent ordinary demand function yields the identity:

(47)

for.

One can derive a theorem concerning the relationships between the price effect of the demand of a commodity and the pure substation effect and the wealth effect in a random horizon stochastic dynamic framework as follows.

Theorem 6.1. Random Horizon Stochastic Dynamic Slutsky Equation

(48)

for, , , and.

Proof. Differentiating the identity (47) with respect to yields:

(49)

for and.

Invoking one can express (49) as:

(50)

To derive the term in a more readily computable form we first note that. To derive the effect on brought about by a change in, with being held constant, we totally differentiate to obtain:

(51)

With and for all and except, Equation (51) becomes

which yields

(52)

Invoking and using (52) one can readily obtain

(53)

Substituting (53) into (50) and invoking the Roy’s identity result in Theorem 4.1, one obtains (48). Hence Theorem 6.1 follows. ■

The random horizon stochastic dynamic Slutsky Equation (48) generalizes the classic Slutsky Equation to a multi-period framework with uncertainties in future income and the consumer’s life span. In particular, the effect of a price change on the demand of a commodity can be decomposed into a pure substation effect and a wealth effect. The left hand side of Equation (48) represents how the demand for good at period changes in response to a change in price, and the first term on the right hand side of the Equation gives the change in demand caused by a change in price holding utility fixed at. The second term on the right hand side of Equation (48) is the product of the change in demand when wealth changes and the required change in wealth brought about by a change in with utility kept fixed at. Thus, the change in the demand of a good caused by a price change can be decomposed into a pure substation effect and a wealth effect.

7. An Illustration with Explicit Utility Function

We consider a consumer with a 2 period horizon. His utility function in period is given by. His initial wealth in Period 1 is. In Period 2 he expects to receive an income with probability for. The probability that the consumer’s life span would end after Period 1 is and the probability that his life span would end after Period 2 is.

The consumer maximizes the expected inter-temporal utility

(54)

subject to the budget dynamics

(55)

7.1. Wealth-Dependent Ordinary Demand

Following the analysis in Section 3, if the consumer lives in Period 2 the wealth-dependent ordinary demand functions in the period can be obtained as:

(56)

The indirect utility function in Period 2 becomes:

(57)

Following the analysis in Section 3 we obtain the wealth-dependent ordinary demand functions in Period 1 as:

Proposition 7.1. The wealth-dependent ordinary demand functions in Period 1 are:

, (58)

where,

(59)

Proof. See Appendix B. ■

Using (59), the inter-temporal indirect utility function in Period 1 can be obtained as:

where is as given in Proposition 7.1.

7.2. Wealth Compensated Demand

Following the analysis in Section 5 we obtain the wealth compensated demands in Period 2 as

for and.

The expenditure function in Period 2 becomes:

(60)

Now we proceed to Period 1. Following the analysis from Equation (37) to Equation (42) the wealth compensated demand function in Period 1 can be obtained as:

Proposition 7.2. The wealth compensated demand functions in Period 1 are:

(61)

for and.

Proof. See Appendix C. ■

Invoking the fact that

one can also have:

for and.  (62)

Proof. See Appendix C. ■

The wealth expenditure function in Period 1 can be expressed as:

(63)

where and are given in (61).

7.3. Random Horizon Slutsky Equation

From (48) we obtain the stochastic dynamic Slutsky equations:

(64)

To verify the duality results and Slutsky equations numerically we consider the illustration in this Section with the following parameter values:

, , and.

In Table 1, the results showing that the ordinary demand equals the wealth-compensated demand, for, are given in the first two rows. The indirect utility and wealth expenditure are given in the third row.

In Table 2, the results for the eight stochastic dynamic Slutsky equations

for, are given as random horizon stochastic dynamic Slutsky Equations (1) to (8). The numerical values of partial derivatives are derived and the Slutsky results are shown in the last row of each equation block.

Table 1. Numerical depiction of wealth-dependent ordinary demands, wealth compensated demands, indirect utility and wealth expenditure.

Table 2. Numerical depiction of the partial derivatives and random horizon stochastic dynamic slutsky equations.

8. Concluding Remarks

This paper extends the conventional consumer analysis to a random horizon stochastic dynamic framework in which the consumer has a planning horizon of periods and there is uncertainty in future incomes and the consumer’s life span. The extension incorporates realistic and essential characteristics of the consumer into conventional consumer theory. The paper derives the Roy’s identity and Slutsky equation for this framework. It is the first time that the Roy’s identity is derived in an inter-temporal setting. With the Roy’s identity the random horizon stochastic dynamic Slutsky is presented in a more comprehensive form than the stochastic dynamic Slutsky equations of Yeung [8]. The analysis advances the microeconomic study on optimal consumption decision to a random horizon stochastic dynamic framework. Further research, development and propagations which explore further economic implications of the results in this paper are in order.

REFERENCES

  1. E. E. Slutsky, “Sulla Teoria Del Bilancio Del Consumatore,” Giornale Degli Economisti, Vol. 51, No. 1, 1915, pp. 1-26.

  2. R. G. D. Allen, “Professor Slutsky’s Theory of Consumers’ Choice,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 3, No. 2, 1936, pp. 120- 129.

  3. R. G. D. Allen, “The Work of Eugen Slutsky,” Econometrica, Vol. 18, No. 3, 1950, pp. 209-216.

  4. J. R. Hicks and R. G. D. Allen, “A Reconsideration of the Theory of Value. Parts 1-2,” Economica, New Series, Vol. 1, No. 1 & 2, 1934, pp. 52-76 & 196-219.

  5. H. Schultz, “Interrelations of Demand, Price, and Income,” Joumal of Political Economy, Vol. 43, No. 4, 1935, pp. 433-481.

  6. P. C. Dooley, “Slutsky’s Equation Is Pareto’s Solution. History of Political Economy,” Vol. 15, No. 4, 1983, pp. 513-517.

  7. T. W. Epps, “Wealth Effects and Slutsky Equations for Assets,” Econometrica, Vol. 43, No. 2, 1975, pp. 301-303.

  8. D. W. K Yeung, “Optimal Consumption under an Uncertain Inter-Temporal Budget: Stochastic Dynamic Slutsky Equations,” Vietsnik St Petersburg University: Mathematics, Vol. 10, No. 3, 2013, pp. 121-141.

  9. R. Roy, “La Distribution Du Revenu Entre Les Divers Biens,” Econometrica, Vol. 15, No. 3, 1947, pp. 205-225.

  10. M. L. Puterman, “Markov Decision Processes: Discrete Stochastic Dynamic Programming” John Wiley & Sons, New York, 1994. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/9780470316887

  11. D. P. Bertsekas and S. E. Shreve, “Stochastic Optimal Control: The Discrete-Time Case,” Athena Scientific, 1996.

  12. D. W. K Yeung and L. A. Petrosyan, “Subgame Consistent Cooperative Solution of Dynamic Games with Random Horizon,” Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, Vol. 150, No. 1, 2011, pp. 78-97.

  13. D. W. K Yeung and L. A. Petrosyan, “Subgame Consistent Solution for Cooperative Stochastic Differential Games with Random Horizon,” International Game Theory Review, Vol. 14, No. 2, 2012, pp. 1250012.01-1250012.22.

  14. R. Bellman “Dynamic Programming,” Princeton University Press, Princeton, 1957.

  15. M. T. Cheung and D. W. K. Yeung, “Microeconomic Analytics,” Prentice Hall, New York, 1995.

Appendices

Appendix A. Proof of Theorem 4.1

Invoking (22) we obtain the identity

(65)

Differentiating (65) with respect to yields:

(66)

Using (32) we have

(67)

Substituting (67) into (66) yields

(68)

Invoking (29) we obtain:

(69)

Using (69) the terms inside the square brackets in (68) can be written as

(70)

Invoking the first order conditions in (23) the term inside the square brackets in (70) vanishes and therefore (68) becomes:

(71)

Using (69), one has

(72)

Substituting (72) into (71) yields

(73)

Invoking (69) one obtains

(74)

Dividing (73) by (74) yields another form of the random horizon Roy’s identity as:

(75)

for and.

Hence Theorem 4.1 follows. Q.E.D.

Appendix B: Proof of Proposition 7.1

The problem facing the consumer in period 1 can be expressed as:

(76)

where

Using the First order condition for a maximizing solution for (76) yields

(77)

Upon rearranging terms (77) can be expressed as:

(78)

Equation (78) can be reduced into a quadratic equation in with roots

, (79)

where,

and.

One can show that both roots are real and positive, and the smaller root yields a utility maximizing solution.

. (80)

Following similar analysis, can be obtained as in Proposition 7.1. Q.E.D.

Appendix C: Proof of Proposition 7.2

The consumer’s dual problem in period 1 can be formulated as minimizing

(81)

subject to the constraint

(82)

Setting up the corresponding Lagrange function of the problem and performing the relevant minimization yield the first order conditions

(83)

where is given in (57).

Invoking and (60) one can readily obtain:

(84)

Using (84), one can reduce the first two equations in (83) to:

(85)

for.

Using (85), one obtains and upon substituting into the last equation of (83) yields

which could be expressed alternatively as:

(86)

Solving from (86) yields the wealth compensated demand for good 1 as:

(87)

Following the above analysis, the wealth compensated demand for good 2 can be obtained as that given in Proposition 7.2. Q.E.D.