Open Journal of Social Sciences, 2014, 2, 30-38
Published Online July 2014 in SciRes. http://www.scirp.org/journal/jss
http://dx.doi.org/10.4236/jss.2014.27006
How to cite this paper: Yang, Y. and Copeland, L. (2014) The Cross-Sectional Risk Premium of Decomposed Market Volatili-
ty in UK Stock Market. Open Journal of Social Sciences, 2, 30-38. http://dx.doi.org/10.4236/jss.2014.27006
The Cross-Sectional Risk Premium of
Decomposed Market Volatility in UK Stock
Market
Yan Yang, Laurence Copeland
Cardiff Business School, Cardiff University, Car diff, UK
Email: yangy16@cardiff.ac.uk, grace_yang@hotmail.co.uk
Received May 2014
Abstract
We decompose UK market volatility into short- and long-run components using EGARCH compo-
nent model and examine the cross-sectional prices of the two components. Our empirical results
suggest that these two components are significantly priced in the cross-section and the negative
risk premia are consistent with the existing literature. The Fama-French three-factor model is
improved by the inclusion of the two volatility components. However, our ICAPM model using
market excess return and the decomposed volatility components as state variables compares infe-
riorly to the traditional three-factor model.
Keywords
ICAPM, Decomposition of Stock Volatility
1. Introduction
The most fundamental and best known model in asset-pricing theory is the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)
which is essentially a “single factor” model of portfolio returns. However, the assumption of a single risk factor
(market beta) limits the validity of this model and the effects of other risk factors have put this model under crit-
icism. Specially, in the late 1970s, a research begins to uncover variables like size, various price ratios, and mo-
mentum that add to the explanation of average returns associated with
β
.
[1] present evidence that beta almost has no explanatory. Their study demonstrates that size and book-to-mar-
ket equity (BE/ME), combined to capture the cross-sectional variation in average stock returns together with the
market
β
, leverage, and earnings-price (E/P) ratios. [2] further suggest that the traditional CAPM does not ac-
count for returns of size and book-to-market sorted portfolios. They show that there are common return factors
related to size and BE/ME that help capture the cross-section of average stock returns in a way that is consistent
with multifactor asset-pricing models.
[3] report the momentum effect that is left unexplained by the three-factor model. [4] constructs a 4-factor
model by including a momentum factor to three-factor model to capture the one-year momentum anomaly. FF
Y. Yang, L. Copeland
31
three -factor model and Carhart’s four-factor model have been widely accepted and employed in empirical ana-
lyses.
In contrast to the lack of theoretical support of three (or four)-factor model, alternative responses to the poor
performance of CAPM are to make modifications to the standard CAPM. Among all the developments, inter-
temporal CAPM and conditional CAPM are most widely applied and various further extensions are proposed to
better interpret the risk-return relation and portfolio structure.
The advocates of conditional CAPM argue that the poor empirical performance of CAPM might be due to the
failure to account for time-variation in conditional moments. Conditional CAPM tries to preserve the single fac-
tor structure of the standard CAPM and assumes that all investors have the same conditional expectations for
their asset returns.
The ICAPM of [5] suggests that when there is stochastic variation in investment opportunities, asset risk pre-
mia are not only determined by covariation of returns with the market return, but also associated with innova-
tions in the state variables that describe the investment opportunities. [6] & [7] points out, in cross-sectional as-
set pricing studies, the factors in the model should be related to innovations in state variables that forecast future
investment opportunities.
There is no doubt that stock market volatility changes over time, but whether or not volatility represents a
priced risk factor remains less certain. [6] & [7] tests the ICAPM and shows that investors care about risks both
from the market return and from changes in forecasts of future market returns. Time-varying market volatility
induces changes in the investment opportunity set by changing the expectation of future market returns, or by
changing the risk-return trade off. [8] develops the ICAPM in a framework in which the conditional means and
variances of state variables are time varying and reflect changes in the investment opportunity set. Risk-averse
investors tend to hedge against exposures to future market volatility. [9] set up a standard two-factor pricing
kernel with the market return and stochastic volatility as factors. They show that market volatility is a significant
cross-sectional asset pricing factor.
[10] develop a new specification to model volatility process based on GARCH. They decompose volatility
into permanent and transitory components. Following [10], the component GARCH model is applied to nu mer-
ous economic areas and different countries1.
[ 11] incorporate the component GARCH model of [10] and the EGARCH model of [12] to build up a new
specification of volatility dynamics, the EGARCH component model. They present that the short- and long-run
volatility components have negative, highly significant prices of risk which is robust across sets of portfolios,
sub -periods, and volatility model specifications.
The motivation for this paper stems from the fact that there are a growing number of papers dealing with the
decomposition of the market volatility into components using Engle and Lee’s component GARCH Model.
However, to my best knowledge, no studies examine the cross-sectional effect of the two decomposed compo-
nents of market volatility, especially on UK stock market. Contrary to the existing empirical studies that simply
employ Engle and Lee’s component GARCH model to explore the time-series effect of volatility, this thesis at-
tempts to understand the cross-sectional effects of the transitory and permanent components of volatility. Fur-
thermore, the EGARCH component framework is implemented together with the simple GARCH component
model. Although Adrian and Rosenberg demonstrate that the short- and long-run volatility components are sig-
nificantly priced in US stock market and their volatility components model compares favorably to the traditional
CAPM, Fama-French model and several other model specifications, we are less confident that their volatility
components are well priced in UK stock market and the superiority of their model.
To test these, we apply the [11] decomposition of market risk to UK stock market and investigate the pricing
of short- and long-run volatility risk in the cross-section of stock returns. The object of this chapter is threefold.
First, we attempt to both determine whether the two components of market volatility are priced risk factors and
estimate the prices of these components. Second, we try to examine whether the short- and long-run component
model remains superior in UK stock markets. Third, we examine the robustness of the volatility component
model across sets of portfolios, sub-periods, and model specifications.
The reminder of this article is organized as follows. Methodology and data description are presented in part II
and part III. Empirical results are reported in part IV. The final section offers concluding remarks.
1
Research include [13] on futures market; [14] on bond market; [15] exploring US stock market; [16] exploring middle-
east stock market;
[17] exploring Malaysia stock market..
Y. Yang, L. Copeland
32
2. Methodology
2.1. Theoretical Motivation of the Pricing of Volatility Risk
The most parsimonious pricing ICAPM framework in which to study the relationship between innovations of
state variables and expected return is given as:
( )
( )
( )
2
,,
M
ERrra covRRcovRz
λ
≈ +∆
(1)
R denotes return in excess of the risk-free rate and
M
R
is stock market excess return. The state variables
z
are the variables that determine how well the investor can do in his maximization.
rra
is the elasticity of mar-
ginal value with respect to wealth and is often referred as the coefficient of relative risk aversion.
When investment opportunities vary over time, the multifactor models of [5] and [18] show that risk premia
are associated with the conditional covariance between asset returns and innovations in state variables that de-
scribe the time-variation of the investment opportunities. And hence, covariance with these innovations will
therefore be priced. In the [6] & [7] ICAPM framework, investors care about risks both from the market return
and from changes in forecasts of future market returns.
[8] extends Campbell’s model and shows that risk-averse investors tend to directly hedge against changes in
future market volatility. Motivated by these multifactor models, [9] express market volatility risk explicitly in
Equation (1),
(2)
where
k
f
represent other factors other than aggregate volatility that induce changes in the investment opportu-
nity set.
For the convenience of empirical application, the above model can be written in terms of factor innovations.
1,
m
t mt
R
γ
+
,
1,t vt
v
γ
+
and
,1 ,kt kt
f
γ
+
represent innovation in the market return, in aggregate volatility risk,
and innovations to the other factors respectively. A true conditional multifactor representation of expected re-
turns in the cross-section would take the following form:
1,1,,1,, ,1,
1
()( )()
K
i iiMii
ttmttmtvtt vtktktkt
k
Ra Rvf
βγβ γβγ
++ ++
=
=+− +−+−
(3)
where
1
i
t
R
+
is the excess return on stock i.
,
i
mt
β
,
,
i
vt
β
and
,
i
kt
β
are the loadings on the excess market return,
on market volatility risk, and on other risk factors, respectively. The conditional mean of the market return, ag-
gregate volatility and other factors are denoted by
,
mt
γ
,
,vt
γ
and
,kt
γ
, respectively. In equilibrium, the condi-
tional mean of stock i is given by
1
()
K
i ii ii
mm vvkk
K
a ER
β λβλβλ
=
== ++
(4)
where
,mt
λ
,
,vt
λ
and
,kt
λ
are the price of risk of the market factor, the price of aggregate volatility risk, and
the prices of risk of the other factors, respectively.
2.2. Econometric Methodology—EGARCH Component Model
As an extension of GARCH model, [10] introduce a component GARCH model where the conditional variance
is decomposed into transitory and permanent components. In this two-component model, transitory and perma-
nent components are used to capture short- and long-term effects of shock, respectively.
Many studies find that two-component volatility model is superior to one-component specification in ex-
plaining equity market volatility and the log-normal model of EGARCH performs better than square-root or af-
fine volatility specifications. Appealed to the merits of the component GARCH and the EGARCH models, [11]
incorporate the features of these two models and specify the dynamics of the market return in excess of risk-free
rate
M
t
R
and the conditional volatility
t
h
as:
Market return:
11
MM
t ttt
R hz
µ
++
= +
(1a)
Market volatility:
ln
ttt
hls= +
(1b)
Shor t-run component:
( )
1451 61
2
t ttt
s szz
θθ θπ
+ ++
=++ −
(1c)
Y. Yang, L. Copeland
33
Long-run component:
1789 1101
( 2)
ttt t
lsz z
θθ θθπ
+ ++
=++ +−
(1d)
( )
... 0,1
t
ziid N
and
M
t
µ
is the one-period expected excess return. The log-volatility is the sum of two
components
t
l
and
t
s
. Each component is an AR(1) processes with its own rate of mean reversion. Without
loss of generality, let
t
l
be the slowly mean-reverting, long-run component and
t
s
be the quickly mean-re-
verting, short-run component
48
()
θθ
<
. The unconditional mean of
t
s
is normalized to zero.
The terms
1
2
t
z
π
+
in Equations (1c) and (1d) are the shocks to the volatility components. Their ex-
pected values are equal to zero, given the normality of
t
z
. For these error terms, equal-sized positive or nega-
tive innovations results in the same volatility change, although the magnitude can be different for the short- and
long -run components (
6
θ
and
10
θ
). The asymmetric effect of returns on volatility is allowed by including the
market innovation in Equations (1c) and (1d) with corresponding coefficients
5
θ
and
9
θ
.
The market model defined by Equations (1a)-(1d) converges to a continuous-time, two-factor stochastic vola-
tility process. An advantage of this specification is that it can be estimated in discrete time via maximum like-
lihood. The daily log-likelihood function is:
( )
( )
( )
2
12 131
11 1
()
1
;,|ln 2,
22
M
Mt tt
ttt tttt
R sl
fs lRslh
θθ θ
θπ
−−
−−
−− −
=−− +−
where t = 1,…, T is the daily time index, T is the total number of daily observations, and
M
t
R
is the daily mar-
ket excess return.
3. Data
We estimate the EGARCH-component volatility model using daily excess returns. The daily data are used in
order to improve the estimation precision and then aggregated to a monthly frequency for the cross-sectional
analysis. FTSE All Share Index with its dividend yield is used as the proxy for the market return,
M
r
, and one
month return on Treasury Bills for the risk free rate,
f
r
. The daily data range from 01/09/1980 to 31/12/2012
and are collected from LSPD (London Stock Price Database) and data stream.
For the cross-sectional price test of the ICAPM, we apply the Fama and French 25 size and BE/ME portfolios
and the portfolio returns and monthly factors are taken directly from [19] website. In the spirit of French’s pro-
vision of the data to the international academic community, [19] construct the Fama and French size and B/M
portfolio and the SMB (size factor), HML (value factor) and UMD (the momentum factor) of UK stock market
and make all portfolios and factors downloadable from their website.
4. Empirical Results
4.1. Results of the Time Series Regression
If the short- and long-run volatility components are also asset pricing factor, in the spirit of the ICAPM, the
equilibrium pricing kernel thus depends on both short- and long-run volatility components as well as the excess
market returns. Denote returns on asset i in excess of the risk free rate by
i
t
R
. The equilibrium expected return
for asset i is:
(5)
whe r e
1
λ
is the coefficient of relative risk aversion, and
s
λ
and
l
λ
are proportional to changes in the margin-
al utility of wealth due to changes in the state variable
t
s
and
t
l
.
Equation (5) shows that expected returns depend on three risk premia. The first risk premium arises from the
covariance of the asset return with the excess market return, multiplied by relative risk a version
1
λ
. This is the
risk-return tradeoff in a static CAPM. The second and third risk premia depend on the covariance of the asset
return with the innovations in the short- and long-run factors.
Market expected return
M
t
µ
is defined as
12 3
M
t tt
sl
µ θθθ
=++
(6)
Examination of the risk-return relation is of fundamental importance to the asset pricing literature. Many au-
thors either fail to detect a statistically significant intertemporal relation between risk and return of the market
Y. Yang, L. Copeland
34
portfolio or find a negative relation2.
The estimation results for the volatility model are shown in Table 1. In the expected return equation, short-run
volatility has a significant positive coefficient
2
θ
, while
3
θ
, the coefficient of long-run volatility is signifi-
cantly negative. The market excess return thus depends positively on short-run volatility but negatively on
long -run volatility. [11] identify a negative relationship between short-run volatility and market excess return but
a positive relationship between long-run volatility and market excess return. Hence, short-run and long-run vola-
tilities seem to have opposite effects on market excess return. This result might explain why previous research
often have difficulty identifying a time-series relationship or mixed results of risk and return relation.
We identify the short- and long-run components by their relative degrees of autocorrelation: the short-run vo-
latility has an autoregressive coefficient of 0.807, and the long-run component has an autoregressive coefficient
of 0.994. The long-run component is highly persistent. However, it’s not permanent, the hypothesis that
81
θ
=
is rejected at the 1% significant level. The estimate of
4
θ
is smaller than that of
8
θ
, which indicates the
short -run volatility is less persistent compared to long-run component. Because the short- and long-run compo-
nents determine log-volatility additively, it’s impossible to identify the means of the two components separately,
and only the mean the long-run component is estimated.
5
θ
and
9
θ
detect the asymmetric effect on volatility.
Both the estimates of
5
θ
and
9
θ
are significantly negative and large than minus one. This suggests that a pos-
itive surprise
( )
t
z
increases both the short- and long-run volatility less than a negative surprise.
Ljun g -box Q statistic suggests that there isn’t remaining serial correlation in the mean equation of the market
excess return, while the ARCH-LM test reveals that there’s no additional ARCH effect exhibiting in the standar-
dized residuals.
4.2. Results of the C ross -Sectional Tests
Monthly data are employed to carry out the cross-sectional tests. The daily short- and long-run volatility com-
ponents are obtained from the time-series regression. The 21-step out-of-sample forecasts of the short- and
long -run components are made respectively. Daily innovations of the volatility components are calculated by
subtracting the short- and long-run component from the forecasted values. The daily innovations in each month
are then aggregated to a monthly frequency, and providing us with the monthly innovations of the short- and
long -run component.
Table 1. Time series estimation of the volatility components, daily, 01/09/1980 to 31/12/2012.
Market excess return:
112 31
M
tt ttt
Rsl hz
θθ θ
++
=+ ++
1
θ
2
θ
3
θ
Coef. 0.007 0.267 0.499
Std.err. 0.010 0.106 0.031
p-value 0.475 0.012 0.000
Short -run component:
1451 6 1
( 2)
t ttt
s szz
θθ θπ
+ ++
=++ −
4
θ
5
θ
6
θ
Coef. 0.807 0.046 0.009
Std.err. 0.030 0.004 0.042
p-value 0.000 0.000 0.829
Long-run component:
178 91101
( 2)
ttt t
llz z
θθ θθπ
+ ++
=++ +−
7
θ
8
θ
9
θ
10
θ
Coef. 0.002 0.994 0.032 0.028
Std.err. 0.000 0.001 0.001 0.002
p-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
2Examples include, [20], [21], and [22].
Y. Yang, L. Copeland
35
21
1([ ]),
N
mttt
t
sress Es
=
= −
(7)
21
1
([ ]),
N
m ttt
t
lresl El
=
= −
(8)
where sres and lres denote innovations of short- and long-run volatility respectively. N is the trading days in
month m. The market variance v is aggregated to a monthly frequency, and the time series follows an AR(2)
process. Hence, variance innovations (vres) are estimated as residuals of a monthly autoregressive process with
two lags. The statistics of the innovations and the other pricing factors are summarized in Table 2.
Under the ICAPM described in Section 2.1, the pricing kernel is a linear function of the excess return on the
market portfolio and the innovations in the state variables, so that the unconditional risk premium on asset i may
be written as:
()
iiiii
mmssl l
a ER
β λβλβλ
== ++
(9)
where
,mt
λ
is the price of risk of the market factor,
,st
λ
is the price of the short-run volatility risk, and the
,lt
λ
is the price of risk of the long-run volatility.
The implication of the ICAPM for stock returns can be tested directly by implementing the two-stage Fa-
ma-MacBeth procedure. We use the correction procedure proposed by [23] to account for the errors-in-variables
problem.
In the first stage, the 25 size and BE/ME portfolio returns are regressed on market excess returns, sres and lres.
In the second stage, the portfolio returns are regressed on the estimated betas from the first stage to obtain the
prices of market risk, short-run volatility risk and long-run volatility risk.
Table 3 reports the pricing of volatility risk in the cross-section. The regressions of CAPM (column i), the FF
three factor model (column ii), Carhart’s momentum model (column iii), and a model analogous to [9] with in-
novations to market variance as risk factor (column iv) are also presented in Table 3.
In column (v), we can see that the short- and long-run volatility components are significant pricing factors at
the 5% level. The prices of short- and long-run components are −0.334 and −0.842 respectively. This implies
that an asset with a short-run volatility beta of unity requires a 0.334% lower returns than an asset with zero ex-
posure to the short-run component. These results are consistent with hypothesis that the cro ss-section of stock
returns reflects exposure to volatility risk. In column (vi) and (vii), the prices of risk when the short- and
long -run volatility enters as separate factors are reported. Each of the components has a negative price of risk at
10% significant level. [6]-[8] show that investors intend to hedge against market volatility and they are willing
to pay a premium for market downside risk. The hedge motive is indicative of a negative price of market volatil-
ity. The negative prices of the decomposed components of market volatility would suggest that risk-averse in-
vestors tempt to hedge the overall exposures to market risk, no matter whether the exposures are transitory or
persistent.
However, the short- and long-run volatility factor compares inferiorly to the FF three-factor model and Car-
hart momentum model, in terms of pricing performance. The RMSPE (root-mean-squared pricing error) are re-
ported to evaluate the pricing performance of the different models. The models with FF factors (column ii and
viii) achieve the lowest pricing errors.
It’s worth noting that adding the two volatility components to FF three-factor model and momentum model
reduces the pricing errors. This suggests that the volatility components and the Fama and French factors (or
Table 2. Summary statistics of the monthly pricing fact o r s .
Pricing factors Mean Std. Dev. Skewness Kurtosis
Short -run volatility(sres) 0.000 1.064 0.309 3.192
Long-run volatility(lres ) 0.000 2.989 1.697 11.083
Market variance (vres) 0.000 14.520 4.429 47. 87
Value factor (HM L) 0.004 0.037 0.270 11.092
Size factor (SMB) 0.001 0.034 0.712 7.200
Momentum factor (UMD) 0.008 0.042 1.258 10.844
Y. Yang, L. Copeland
36
Table 3. Pricing the cross section of the 25 size and B/M sorted portfolios.
(i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi) (vii ) (viii) (ix)
Excess market
return
Coef. 0.596 0.454 0.498 0.439 0.453 0.608 0.465 0.443 0.438
p-valu e 0.033 0.073 0.073 0.083 0.073 0.026 0.066 0.080 0.084
Short -run volatility
(sres)
Coef. 0.334 0.265 0.232 0.287
p-valu e 0.047 0.097 0.091 0.062
Long-run volatility
(lres)
Coef. 0.842 0.602 0.623 0.689
p-valu e 0.034 0.071 0.074 0.057
Market variance
(vres)
Coef. 3.251
p-valu e 0.049
Value factor
(HML)
Coef. 0.518 0.518
p-valu e 0.025 0.024
Size factor
(SMB)
Coef. 0.165 0.156
p-valu e 0.386 0.212
Momentum factor Coef. 0.890 0.801
(UMD) p-value 0.029 0.076
RMSPE 0.210 0.120 0.142 0.245 0.188 0.210 0.197 0.113 0.138
This table reports the two-stage cr oss-sectional regression results for the 25 size and B/M sorted portfolios under various model specifications, in-
cluding ICAPM, FF three-factor model, and the CAPM. The t-ratios are calculated using Jagannathan and Wang (1998) and Newey and West (1987)
procedures to account for the estimation errors in first-stage estimation and correct for the possible heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation. The cor-
responding p-values are reported according to the adjusted t-ratios. Root mean square pricing errors (RMPSE) are reported.
momentum factors) capture some orthogonal source of priced risk.
The first-stage FM regression shows that the factor loadings have significant variation across the size di-
mension, however but less significant varation across the B/M dimension3.
Table 4 shows the risk premium on the 25 size and BE/ME portfolios. The price spread of market risk
between small firms and large firms is 0.107, which translate into an annualized premium spread due to market
risk of 1.3% per year. Similarly, the annualized premium spreads between small and large firms due to
short -run volatility and long-run volatility are 1.76% and 4.14% respectively. Only the risk premium of the
long -run volatility is positive, but with much bigger magnitude. Hence, combining the three risk-premium dif-
ferences yields an average excess risk premium for small firm relative to large firms of 1.08%. The analysis
suggests that the size effect of small cap firms earning higher risk adjusted returns may be attributed to the
long -run volatility component.
The difference of annualized risk premium between the high B/M firms and low B/M firms due to the risk of
short -run volatility component is 0.50% per year, while the difference due to the long-run component is 0.33%
per year. Hence, the short- and long-run volatility components have the same effect on the B/M firm portfolio.
Combining the value spread due to market risk, the total effect that the high B/M firm portfolio earns 1.32%
higher risk premium per year relative to low B/M firm portfolio. The analysis suggests that the B/M effect that
high B/M firms earn higher returns may be explained by both the short- and long-run volatility components.
4.3. Robustness Tests4
In order to test the robustness of the results we find above, we proceed the following tests:
1) Estimate the models using three sub-periods of the whole sample periods.
2) The cross-sectional procedure is regressed on returns of different portfolios sorted by other criteria.
3) Different mean equations are specified to test the EGARCH component model.
4) We compare EGARCH component model with GARCH and GARCH component model by evaluate their
3For reasons of space, the results are available upon a request from the author.
4The test procedures and results are available upon a request.
Y. Yang, L. Copeland
37
Table 4. Factor risk premia of the 25 size and B/M sorted portfolios.
Market risk premium
Small Size 2 Size 3 Size 4 Big Average
Gr o wt h 0.392 0.421 0.4489 0.443 0.427 0.427
B/M 2 0.332 0.380 0.423 0.417 0.435 0.398
B/M 3 0.305 0.368 0.403 0.396 0.480 0.390
B/M 4 0.327 0.357 0.404 0.480 0.431 0.400
Value 0.313 0.378 0.403 0.462 0.429 0.397
Average 0.334 0.381 0.416 0.439 0.441 0.402
Short -run volatility risk premium
Small Size 2 Size 3 Size 4 Big Average
Gr o wt h 0.213 0.102 0.124 0.072 0.069 0.106
B/M 2 0.247 0.184 0.059 0.042 0.037 0.092
B/M 3 0.139 0.186 0.109 0.079 0.080 0.056
B/M 4 0.152 0.045 0 .0 11 0.084 0.054 0.039
Value 0.125 0.050 0.022 0. 113 0.000 0.065
Average 0.175 0.096 0.052 0.029 0.027 0.076
Long-run volatility risk premium
Small Size 2 Size 3 Size 4 Big Average
Gr o wt h 0.357 0.212 0.104 0.249 0.035 0.177
B/M 2 0.393 0.341 0.074 0.184 0.032 0.205
B/M 3 0.339 0.286 0.105 0.225 0.045 0.200
B/M 4 0.332 0.286 0.069 0.215 0.109 0.202
Value 0.361 0.341 0.116 0.287 0.079 0.205
Average 0.357 0.293 0.094 0.232 0.014 0.198
This table reports the risk premia of portfolio returns on the market excess return, short-run volatility innovations and long-run volatility innovations.
The risk premia are computed by multiplying factor loadings from Fama-Macbeth first-stage regression and prices of risk of Table 3, column V,
second stage Fama-Mac Bethregressoin.
performance in the cross-sectional pricing.
The magnitudes of the prices of risk for the volatility components are fairly similar across different sets of assets
and sample periods. The benchmark specification is superior to the alternatives with lowest root-mean-squared error.
5. Conclusions
ICAPM predicts that financial asset risk premia are not only due to covariation of returns with the market excess
return, but also associated with innovations in the state variables that describe the investment opportunities.
Multifactor models of risk already predict that aggregate volatility should be a cross-sectional risk factor. [11]
further decompose the aggregate volatility into a transitory and a permanent component. They conclude that the
short - and long-run volatility components have negative, highly significant prices of risk using American stock
market data.
Applying decomposition of market risk to UK stock market, we find that the short- and long-run volatility
components also have significantly negative prices of risk. The results are robust across sets of portfolios, sam-
ple periods and model specifications. The short- and long-run volatility might provide an explanation of the size
and value anomaly of financial market. Specifically, the size effect of small cap firms earning higher risk ad-
Y. Yang, L. Copeland
38
justed returns may be attributed to the long-run volatility component. Whereas, the value effect that high B/M
firms earn higher returns may be explained by both the short- and long-run volatility components. However, the
performance of the decomposition model is superior to the Fama-French three factor model, and [9] market va-
riance model. This might suggest further investigation and improvement on Adrian and Rosenberg’s volatility
decomposition model.
References
[1] Fama, E.F. and French, K.R. (1992) The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns. The Journal of Finance, XLVII,
427-465. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1992.tb04398.x
[2] Fama, E.F. and French, K.R . (199 3) Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds. Journal of Financial
Economics, 33, 3-56. htt p:// d x.do i.o rg/1 0.10 16 /03 04-405X(93)90023-5
[3] Jegadeesh, N. and Titman, S. (199 3) Returns to Buying Winners and Selling Losers: Implications for Stock Market Ef-
ficiency. The Journal of Finance, 48, 65-91. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1993.tb04702.x
[4] Carhart, M.M. (1997) On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance. The Journal of Finance, 52, 57-82.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1997.tb03808.x
[5] Merton , R.C. (1973) An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model. Econometrica , 51, 867-887.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1913811
[6] Campbell, J.Y. (1993) Intertemporal Asset Pricing without Consumption Data. American Economic Review, 83, 487 -
512.
[7] Campbell, J.Y. (1996) Understanding Risk and Return. Journal of Political Economy, 104, 298 -34 5.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/262026
[8] Chen, J. (2002) In tertempo ral, CAPM and the Cross-section of Stock Returns. Working P aper , University of Southern
California, Los Angeles.
[9] Ang, A. , Hodrick, R. J., Xing, Y.H. and Zhang, X.Y. (2006) The Cross-Section of Volatility and Expected Returns. The
Journal of Finance, LXI , 259-299. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261 .20 06 .00 836. x
[10] Engl e, R.F. and Lee, G. (1999) A Permanent and Transitory Component Model of Stock Return Volatility. Cointegra-
tion, Causality and Forecasting: A Festschrift in Honor of Clive W.J. Granger. Oxford University Press, New York.
[11] Adr ian, T. and Rosenberg, J. (2008) Stock Returns and Volatility: Pricing the Short-Run and Long-Run Components of
Market Risk. The Journal of Finance, 63, 2997 -30 30. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2008.01419.x
[12] Nelson, D.B. (19 91 ) Conditional Heteroskedasticity in Asset Returns: A New Approach. Economet rica, 59 , 347 -370.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2938260
[13] Macmillan, H. and Tampoe, M. (2000) Strategic Management. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
[14] Simó n, S.R. and Amalia, M.Z. (2012) Volatility in EMU Sovereign Bond Yields: Permanent and Transitory Compo-
nents. Applied Financial Economics, 22, 14 53-14 64. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09603107.2012.661397
[15] Hertog, R.G.J.D. (1994) Pricing of Permanent and Transitory Volatility for US Stock Returns: A Composite GARCH
Model. Economics Letters, 44, 421 -426. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0165-1765(94 )90 115 -5
[16] Zarour, B . A. and Siriopoulos, C .P . (2008) Transitory and Permanent Volatility Components: The Case of the Middle
East Stock Markets. Review of Middle East Economics and Finance, 4, 80-92.
[17] Mansor, H.I and Huson, J.A.A. (2014) Permanent and Transitory Oil Volatility and Aggregate Investment in Malaysia.
Energy Po lic y, 67 , 552 -563. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2013.11.072
[18] Ross, S.A. (1976) The Arbitrage Theory of Capital Asset Pricing. Journal of Economic Theory, 13, 341-360.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(76)90046-6
[19] Grego ry, A., Thar yan, R. and Huang, A. (2009) The Fama-French and Momentum Portfolios and Factors in the UK.
University of Exeter Business School, XFI Centre for Finance and Investment Paper No. 09/05.
[20] Baillie, R.T. and Degennaro, R.P. (1990) Stock Returns and Volatility. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis,
25, 203-214. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2330824
[21] Whitelaw, R. (1994) Time Variations and Covariations in the Expectation and Volatility of Stock Returns. Journal of
Finance, 49, 515-541. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1994.tb05150.x
[22] Harve y, C.R. (2001) The Specification of Conditional Expectations. Journal of Empirical Finance, 8, 573-638.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0927-5398(01)00036-6
[23] Jagannat han, R. and Wang, Z.Y. (1998) An Asymptotic Theory for Estimating Beta-Pricing Models Using Cross-Sec-
tional Regression. Journal of Finance, 53, 1285-1309. ht tp :// dx. doi.o rg/ 10. 11 11/ 0022 -10 82.0 0053