Sociology Mind
2014. Vo l.4, No.1, 45-50
Published Online January 2014 in SciRes (h ttp://www.scirp.org/journal/sm) http://d x.doi.org/10.4236/sm.201 4.41006
Economic and Cultural Peripheralization in the Eurozone
Antonio Luigi Paolilli
University of Salento, Lecce, Italy
Email: apaolilli@alice.it
Received S eptember 5th, 2013; revised October 11th, 2013; accepted November 22nd, 2013
Copyright © 2014 Antonio Luigi Paolilli. Th is i s an open access arti c le distri bu ted und er the C reati ve Comm ons
Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the
original work is properly cited. In accordance of the Creative Commons Attribution License all Copyrights ©
2014 a re reserved for SC IRP and the owner of the int ellect ual p ropert y Antonio Luigi Paolilli. All Copyri ght ©
2014 are guarded b y law and by SCIRP as a guardian.
In this paper, we will discus s the reasona bleness of the decision b y It aly and other southern an d western
EU sta t es t o bec ome me mber s of t he euroz one. We wi l l a l so di s cuss whether thi s economic choice can be
socially and culturally sustainable in a Europe characterized by cultures which, despite their shared sub-
stratum, are in competi tion with each other.
Key words: Peripheralization; Social Cohesion; Economic History
Introduction
In 1992 when Italy left the EMS with a great devaluation,
above all compared to the Deutsche mark1, it was not alone,
because the pound sterling also withdrew from the EMS. The
United Kingdom, however, did not join the eurozone, unlike
Italy and other outlying states of the EU. In this paper, we will
discuss the reasonableness of the decision by Italy and other
southern and western EU members, in the light of the com-
ments made in some recent papers. We will also examine the
issue of whether this economic choice can be socially and cul-
turally sustainable in a Europe characterized by cultu res which,
despite their shared substratum, are in competition with each
other.
Restrictive Policies, Finance and
Peripheralization Processes
The years following the outbreak of the Global Financial
Crisis have been characterized in most eurozone states, and
above all in the so called PIIGS, by a great accel eration o f aus-
terity policies consisting, besides further deregulation of the
labor market, essentially of a reduction of public spending and
in an increase in taxes, in order to achieve a balanced public
budget. In the view of supporters of austerity, even though
these fiscal policies were brought in during a crisis, and there-
fore even though they cause a worsenin g of the recession, they
should in the long term lead to a lasting economic recovery.
This app roach has aroused radical criticism. It has been argued
in fact that austerity policies not only herald recession, but they
are also ineffective and even produce the opposite effect to the
purpose of reducing the public debt/GDP ratio (Forges Davan-
zati, 2 013 ; Cesaratto & Pivetti, 2012), due to the consequent re-
cessive spiral which reduces the tax base.
These criticisms, however, seem feeble to the advocates of
austerity who, above all in the German area, believe that the
differences among th e perfor mances o f the variou s EU me mber
states are essentially caused by the different approaches taken
by governments and even by the populations, which can be
divided, in their opinion, into “cicadas” (spenders) and “ants”
(savers).
It has been shown, however (Paolilli, 2011a; Paolilli & Pol-
lice, 2 011b ) that the p eripheralizatio n processes are mostl y due
to geographical factors, stressing moreover the role that mone-
tary and financial institutions have in territorial dynamics. Ac-
cording to this viewpoint, the financialization of the economy,
into the broader scenario of globalization, can reinforce cumu-
lative processes which widen the pre-existing territorial gaps.
Specifically, it has been shown, by means of a mathematical
model, th at di sadvan taged regio ns can en d up financi ng, at least
indirectly, the economic activities of those areas from which
they have received direct investments. In fact, when a growth
process begins in a region, it tends to extend to other areas, but
the outcome of the investments in those areas is essentially
dependent on some of their geographical and cultural characte-
ristics. There are in fact various types of peripheral countries,
which can be grouped essentially into two categories. The real
peripheries (which we can call peripheries of type A), are usu-
ally near the central areas (but not close enough to be progres-
sively absorbed by them). They experience the economic and
cultural influence of central areas, also due to workers’ emula-
tive tendencies, but they could never reach the same levels of
productivity and welfare (the comparison South-North of Italy
is a good example of this scenario). In fact we can assu me that
productivity is also a function of the worker’s effort. It must be
consi dered that th e s maller the gap between the act ual wage and
the target wage, the greater the effort, and that in the mind of
workers of type A peripheries the target wage can be the same
as that perceived by workers in central areas. Therefore, given
the lower productivity of the peripheral regio ns (due to the fact
that these areas are less interested by cumulative processes of
economic growth), we can deduce that in type A peripheries
1Amato’s Government took the decision to get of EMS and to devalue the
lira only after a strong, enduring and by then unsustainable attach of the
market.
OPEN ACCE SS 45
A. L. PAOLILLI
there is a vicious circle: low productivity, low wages; little ef-
fort, low productivity. In contrast, the peripher ies which are se-
parated fro m the cen tral ar eas b y means o f p h ysical, po li tical or
cultural barriers, and which we will call peripheries of type B,
even though they may experience economic dependence, can
easily overcome it if they have adequate physical and human
resour ces.
Besides showing the existence of a natural conflict between
financers an d producers, in which finance seems to have a nat-
ural aptitude to absorb industrial profits, the model in the work
cited above also shows that interest rates in peripheral areas
tend to be higher than in central areas. This phenomenon hind-
ers the local enterprises which, at least in the initial phase of
their growth, are small and therefore not able to easily obtain
direct financing. The model, then, explains the prevalence of in-
direct financial flows (i.e. carried out through banks) from pe-
ripheral regions to central areas, flows which tend to counter-
balance the diffusive effects of direct investments from central
areas towards peripheral ones. The counterbalancing effect of
indirect flows, moreover, is particularly deleterious for type A
peripheries. These areas are often bypassed by direct funding,
because the geographic and cultural proximity to central areas
tends to raise t he target wages, re du cing effort and t herefore la-
bor productivity, if real wages are significantly lower than tar-
get wages. The vicious circle we have seen above is then rein-
forced by th e finan cial d ynamics: t he differenc e b etween th e in -
terest rate applied in central and peripheral areas, particularly
type A (bu t also in type B, at least whil e they remain on th e pe-
riphery), consolidate the processes of cumulative causation which
increase t he difference i n produ ctivity between th e two types of
regions.
The theoretical considerations we have explained above are
corroborated by what happens in the real world. As noted by
Spratt (2009: p. 67), the liberalization started under Reagan’s
presidency caused a much higher interest rate rise than ex-
pected, above all in poor countries. Spratt also points out that,
unexpectedly, i.e. contrary to the provisions of orthodox eco-
nomic theory, many studies have shown that growth of real in-
terest rates has often led to a fall in accumulation rates. Ex-
amining the financial flows in the Nineties and early years of
this millennium, first, the author observes that, again contrary
to the forecasts by advocates of liberalization, they have not fol-
lowed a linear trend, but cyclical behavior, with an alternation
of growths and declines. Moreover, with the exclusion of direct
financing, financial flows between developed countries and
emerging areas have not only fluctuated, but have periodically
changed direction too, resulting in a balance showing a net flow
from developing regions to developed areas. Furthermore, we
must stress that the financial flows studied by Spratt are those
between developed regions and emerging areas, which can be
classified as type B p eripheries. As we will al so see below, the
dynamics are presumably even more pernicious for type A pe-
riph er i es.
Europe before the Integration: A Singular Case
of Cooperation and Competition
From the discussion above we can deduce that many prob-
lems may derive by the increasing connectivity of the world, if
not adequately regulated.
As far as Europe is concerned, these problems are exacer-
bated by the adoption of a single currency, which is not coun-
terbalanced by the existence of a single state. National curren-
cies, in fact, were a sort of barrier amongst the various econo-
mies of the Union, without, however, greatly reducing their
trade with each other. Trade was int ense but it was adjusted b y
the rising and falling of national currencies. The resulting situa-
tion, therefore, can be called an optimal combination of coop-
eration and competition.
The v iew that productivity can be higher if there is a balanc-
ed combination of competition and cooperation is underlined by
Diamond (2006, 1997: pp. 357, 360-361). It has been noted, for
example, that technological progress, in modern industrial
companies, is favored by a balanced mix of competition and
circulation of information (which may be regarded as a form of
cooperation). Big compani es which are hierarchically organized
seem less efficient than others, equally large but composed of
relativel y indepen dent units competing with each other, but not
so much as to prevent information circulating among them.
With regard to economic and political systems, it has been
observed (Paolilli & Pol lice, 2011a), b y means of a mathemati -
cal model, that the greater the competition and/or the less the
cooperation and emulation, the lower the number of EPS (eco-
nomic-pol iti cal systems) in a geograp h ical ar ea. The mod el als o
shows th at technolo gical progress all ows an EPS to incr ease its
area of influence, reducing the economic role of the EPS that
are unab le to rapidly renew th eir tech nological level or to adop t
strategies to diversify their production, specializing in the use
of other resources.
Since the Middle Ages Europe has been characterized by a
singular combination of cooperation and competition. Coopera-
tion was based on a common (Christian) culture, also favored
by the use o f Latin by the ed ucated and the clergy, while co m-
petition arose from the fact that it was difficult for societies
whose economy was not based on sea trade as in Ancient Times
(due to Islamic and other invasions in the Mediterranean basin),
to unify in a single EPS. According to recent studies (Paolilli &
Pollice, 2011a), this combination has probably been the main
factor which allowed Europe, rather than other EP S, like China
or the Roman empire, to undertake the development towards
Modernity (see also Scheidel, 2007; Paolilli, 2008). It is inter-
esting the make a comparison with China which, apart some
short periods, was always more cohesive than Europe. It was
precisely for this reason that, although 15th-century China was
equipped with technologies which would allow it to undertake
the development towards Modernity (its enormous fleet sailed
and explored the Indian ocean), it only took a polit ical upheaval
led by a few individuals at the top of the institutions to cause
the total abandonment of expansionist policy and the isolation
of that great nation (Diamond, 2006, 1997: p. 318).
The mix of cooperation and competition, then, enabled Eu-
rope to evolve towards Modernity because of the application of
innovations was favored by the ease of disseminating ideas and
at the same time it was necessitated by the fact that the conti-
nental EPS were competing with each other.
This, of course, does not necessarily mean that the optimal
dimension for the European countries in the current global
competition is still that of the single nation.
We must consider, in fact, that increasing globalization, fa-
vored by the speed of communications and the lowering of their
costs, has changed the scale of competition from a regional or
sub-continental context to a global one. In the present time,
EPS the size of China do not risk being isolated. Their eco-
nomic systems are in fact increasingly interconnected with the
OPEN ACCE SS
46
A. L. PAOLILLI
others and are therefore stimulated to a competition and coop-
eration that are almost irreversible.
With regard to Europe, the process of integration and coop-
eration was increased by the establishment after the Second
World War of an area of free trade, eliminating the possibility
of wars, without however reducing that degree of competition
which, t ogether with coop eration, as we have s een abo ve, is th e
main factor of progress. The single stat es of the Euro pean Com-
mon Market, in other words, cooperated more than in any other
previous periods, but their single economic systems were mu-
tuall y protected again st excessive co mpetiti on which cou ld lead
to cent ralization and therefore perip heralization du e to monet a-
ry barriers.
The establ ishment of the E MS (March 13, 1979) had already
reduced the amplitude of such barriers, further facilitating trade
thanks to a careful control of exchange rates between EU cur-
rencies. This control, however, ended up replacing a series of
fluctuations in currency exchange rates, which could have re-
gulated the trade relations between the countries, with one great
final currency crisis which broke up the EMS2.
The introduction of the Euro was not accompanied by the
creation of a central government to implement a significant re-
distribution of income. There continue to exist many states re-
sponsible for administering public affairs without however be-
ing able to issue currency while the monetary barriers between
the EU Economic-Political Systems that adopted the euro have
been demol ished , creating a kin d of “monopol y game” between
the same economies. This has produced a concentration of fi-
nancial resources, and therefore also of real resources, in the
hands of a few and of the central areas of the Union.
The phenomenon of concentration has not been stressed by
the mainstr eam eco n omists, but it has been widely discussed by
econo mic geograph ers, from the “cu mulat iv e causat io n” of My-
rdal (1957) to the “New Economic Geography” of Krugman
(1991, 1998). The tendency to concentration, moreover, has
also bee n obs e r v e d in ot he r scientific cont ext s.
Almost every branch of science i n fact recognizes the relev-
ance of so-called “power law, according to which it can be ob-
served that in nature the most diverse phenomena, like the im-
portance of rivers and stars, have a negative exponential rela-
tionship with their size3. This phenomenon has been observed
also in the concentration of wealth (in all the social and politi-
cal contexts), where it takes the name of P areto distribut io n (see
Mandelbrot, 1963), contradicting the opinions of those who
think that market forces will naturally generate an optimal and
eve n equi ta bl e dis t ri b ut ion of resources.
Peripheries: The Cases of East Germany
and South of Italy
With regard to the differen ces b etween th e econo mic systems
of Northern Europe and the Mediterranean European states, it
has often been stressed that the latter need to comply with the
former, in the belief that their failures deri ve above all from bad
economic policies and bad habits, disinclined to austerity. We
have been given, as an example to follow, the case of the unifi-
cation of Germany, which would experience a rapid conver-
gence between its East and West parts, following the reunifica-
tion process which started in 1989.
In actu al fact it is a rath er inter esting case b ecause, u nlike th e
cases of P ortugal, Greece, I reland and Spain, it i s not related to
a whole state, but to a part of it, and it is therefore more com-
parabl e to the Italian situat ion, historically charact erized by the
North-So uth gap. If we con sider, moreover, t hat East German y
was annexed to West Germany and that it has suffered the po-
litical and economic hegemony of the latter, the similarity with
the case of Southern Italy is even stronger: East Germany, like
Southern Italy, can be defined a type A periphery.
The recent economic history of East Germany, however, is
rather different from that of Southern Italy4. Unlike the latter, in
fact, before the Second World War East Germany had one of
the most advanced industrial systems in the world and its per
capita GDP was higher than that of th e western part of Germa-
ny. Moreover, besides being the seat of the political capital,
East German y was l arger t han it i s n ow and was at th e cent re of
important trade with the S lav countries. After the war, however,
membership of the CMEA deteriorated the product competi-
tiveness o f East Ger many and on re-ent ry into a market system,
this caused such serious difficulties of adaptation that the sur-
vival of man y businesses was threatened. To carr y out the rea-
lignment process in East Germany, as in the Italian case, an
“extraord in ary inter vent io n” was mad e. Ho wever, while i n I taly
this intervention interested large-scale industry, in Germany it
covered mainly small and medium-size enterprises. East Ger-
many suffered a dramatic initial depression caused, in the opi-
nion of many observers, by the decision to achieve economic
union as quickly as possible and above all to impose an equal
exchange rate between the Western and Eastern mark. The lat-
ter, even though it was difficult to determine its actual value,
given the great differences between the two economic and so-
cial syste ms, was mu ch weak er than the former (Burker, 2009).
Nevertheless the eastern regions have made great progress to-
wards economic integration with West Germany.
It should be noted, however, that since 2004, due to the ac-
cession of several Eastern European states, East Germany, un-
like southern Italy, is no longer a periph er al area, at least from a
strictly geographic point of view (moreover, unlike Southern
Italy, it is the seat of the country’s political center). In fact in
recent years, perhaps as a result of the increased centrality of
the area, a further convergence of per capita incomes of the
“two Germanies” seems t o be underway.
However, unlike most regions of southern Italy, almost all
the regio ns of East Germany have exp erienced a signi ficant re-
duction of population, both in relative terms (i f co mpared to th e
rest of German y), and in absolute terms (see F i gures 1 and 2).
East Ger many, in oth er words, h as not in creased its wealth sig-
nificantly, but has rather divided it among fewer people. This
phenomenon is illustrated, with regard to the demographic
trends and for the period 1989-2004, by Figure 1. For the pe-
riod 2004-2008 the thematic map of Figure 2 shows the rela-
tive variations of population at level NUTS 2 (regional level).
The graph in Figure 3 shows instead the changes in productiv-
2It has b een argued that in th e years following th e collapse of t he EMS, in
spite of the devaluation of the Italian lira, there was a decrease in Italian
sha r e of
Europe an GDP and of European
and world exports. This is not t rue
if we consider per capita revenue and exports, i.e. if we take into account
the reduction of the relative weight of the Italian population. Per capita ex-
ports, for example, between
1992 and 2001 increased by 42% in Ita
ly, while
in France, Germany and the USA they increased, respectively, only by 34%
40% a n d 37% (Fa i ni , 2 00 3).
3
It was the application of power law (Buchanan, 2008, pp. 183-
184) that
allowed researchers to verify that t
he furrows excavated on Mars are a
c-
tually relics of ancient basins and therefore on that planet there were once
considerable quantities of watery liquid.
4About this topic see also C. Vita (2006-2007), pp. 87-92.
OPEN ACCE SS 47
A. L. PAOLILLI
ity in German y’s eastern regi on s, exp ressed in per cent age terms
compared t o that of th e western regions. We can easily not e that
productivity, after a fall following the unification, quickly reco-
vered and progressively but more and more slowly approached
the productivity of the western regions, without reaching it. Fi-
gure 4 compares per capita income rate of the eastern regions
with that of the western parts of Germany. It is interesting to
examine, las tl y, the gr aph in Figure 5, which shows the relat ive
performance (compared to the western part of Germany) of
East Germany’s GDP. In this case too the initial fall and the
later reco very are clearl y visible. We can see, however, that t he
recover y of th e global GDP, un like the per capita GDP , almost
completely stops after the mid-1990s, remaining on signifi-
cantly lower values th an tho se b efore unification. Clearly this is
due to the population reduction of Eastern Germany: the East
Germany resulting after the integration process is a demo-
graphi cally a relati vel y smaller o ne, al thou gh, at th e same time,
characterized by greater per capit a income.
Southern Italy, instead, has continued to be a real periphery.
Moreo ver, it h as been experien cing this st ate for a con siderab ly
longer time than East Germany and has therefore already suf-
fered large scale migration in the past. However, it should be
noted that migration, this time concerning skilled workers
above all, seems to be again affecting not only southern Italy
but also the whole of Italy, which will perhaps start to assume a
peripheral status in its entirety.
UE, Nationalities and Social Cohesion
From the discussion above we can deduce that if on the one
hand it seems unrealistic that the single national Eu ro pean
states can continue to play a decisive role i n the global scenario,
on the other hand it is clear that the adoption of a single cur-
ren cy, without appropriate redistributive measures and indeed
in combination with restrictive policies, is generating a reces-
sion so marked that it is pushing many European states toward
stagnation and economic, social and in so me cases e ven cultural
decline. In fact we must not forget that the states which are
members of EU are essentially nations, with thousands of years
of history, albeit with a common cultural substratum. The eco-
nomic differences among the EU member states cannot be bri-
dged, if instead of the competitive evaluations and public in-
terventions (welfare) of the past, the only strategy used is defla-
tionary policies which definitely generate migration causing po-
pulation depletion and the reduction of the political weight of
entire nationalities. Inter-European migrations cannot be com-
pared to those concerning single-nation states. What makes a
cohesive societ y is in fact a p articular hu man apt itude: Ben tha-
mian altruism. In humankind, in fact, both groups and individ-
uals are vehicles of selection, the former due to Benthamian
Figure 1.
Evolut ion of the relat ive weight of the eastern region s on the Ger-
many population in the period 1989-2006 (% values). Source:
Mar tinez Oliva, 200 9. In the work of Oliva the percentages of the
Eastern Germany population erroneously refer to the Western Ger-
many popula t i o n a l o n e .
Figure 2.
Relative variations of the population in the regions (Nuts2) of Germany in the period 2004-2008. Source: Eurostat.
OPEN ACCE SS
48
A. L. PAOLILLI
Figure 3.
Evolution of the productivity level in East Germany and West
Germany in the period 1989-2006 (% values). Source: Martinez
Oliva, 2009.
Figure 4.
Evolution of the per capita GDP of East Germany and West
Germany in the period 1989-2006 (% values). Source: Martinez
Oliva, 2009.
Figure 5.
Evolution of the weight of the eastern regions in the German
GDP in the period 1989-2006 (% values). Source: Martinez
Oliva, 2009.
altruism, which is directed toward the group5, therefore favor-
ing its cohesion (Paolilli, 2011b), while the individual is related
to a combination of selfishness and “binary altruism”, which is
directed towards single humans (Paolilli, 2011b; see also Bia-
vati, Sandri, & Zarri, 2002; Forges Davanzati, & Paolilli, 2004).
Benthamian altruism requires, as a priority, an identification
in the group and this identification, of course, is much easier
the more the individuals share cultural, economic, social and
also territorial elements.
A E uro pean Union characterized by many nationalities can-
not work if it is based on a structure which, to sustain itself,
requires continual sacrifices which, moreover, do not seem to
serve the collective well-being but instead, in deference to du-
bious economic th eories, feed finan cial in terests whose p roduc-
tivity for the whole community is unproven (on this, see Forges
Davanzati, 2013). Euro zone countries must manage the appa-
ratus of their public administration without monetary sovere-
ignty. Ther efore esp ecially tho se who are economicall y and/ or
politically weaker, end up either being subject to financial au-
thorities like th ose, not democratically elected ( and whose goals
may differ from those of the majority of the population), or
strongly influenced by the stronger political (and national) enti-
ties.
All this, in the long run, could cause a decline in identifica-
tion with the EU, with political and social consequences. In fact
social inequality tends to encourage behaviors which under-
mine the institutions both in those who profit from this inequa-
lity and, of course, in those who lack power and wealth (Glaes-
er & Shleifer, 2002; Glaeser, Scheinkman, & Shleifer, 2003;
see also Buchanan, 2008: pp. 200-203). Moreover, when there
is a moral distance between benefactors and beneficiaries (in
the sense that the latter are not seen by the former as members
of their group), the benefactors’ willingness to act unselfishly
depends more on considerations of effectiveness (Anen, 2007).
In other words, individuals no longer continue to act unselfishly
towards st rangers if the y think that th eir actions are ineffecti ve,
unlike the case in where emotional proximity is more intense
and there is therefore less rationality (pushing behaviors which
are apparently less rational but that generate a social cohesion
which is at the basis of human societies).
Conclusion
In the light of the considerations that we have done above,
we can conclude that it seems difficult to build a truly unified
and d emocratic Europe starting from a monetary union. The n it
would be more appropriate to build a Europe that is unified in
some respects (e.g. with centralization of government spending
for some strategic branches of the Public Administration), but
consist of EPS that are more autonomous from the economic
point of view, and therefore be able to implement fiscal policies.
In other words, to make an analogy with the banking system,
Europe should be set up not on the German model of universal
bank, which operates in any monetary and financial field, but
on that of the multi-purpose group, in which a central manage-
ment with strategic functions co-exists with many peripherals
which are almost independent from each other and that operate
in the specific field s in which th ey are s pecialized .
As we have s een above, i n fact, a care ful combinati on of co-
operation and competition is what has allowed not only Euro-
pean EPS, but also successful companies to grow and prosper.
Acknowledgements
I thank Guglielmo Forges Davanzati (University of Salento)
for some useful suggestions.
REFERENCES
Anen, C. (2007). Neural correlates of economic and mor al deci sion-ma-
king. http://thesis.libr ary.caltech.edu/1561/
Biavati, M., Sandri, M., & Zarri, L. (2002). Preferenze endogene e di-
na mich e relazion ali: Un modello coevolu tivo (Endogenou s preferen-
ces and relational dynamics: A coevolutionary model). In P. L. Sacco,
& S. Zamagni (Eds.), Complessità relazionale e comportamento eco-
nomico (Relational complexity and economic behavior) (pp. 431-
5The group, nat ura lly, inc ludes the agent, who sees himse lf as an elem ent of
the group.
OPEN ACCE SS 49
A. L. PAOLILLI
485). B ologna, IL: Mulino.
Buchanan, M. (2008). L’atomo sociale. Il comportamento umano e le
leggi della fisica, Milan, Mondadori, Italian edition of The Social
Atom (2008 ) .
Burker, M. (2009). The Economic unification of Germany, L’Arengo
del viaggiatore (The arengo of the traveler), Section Economia e
Mercati (Economics and m ar kets), 64.
Cesaratto, S., & Pivetti, M. (2012). Oltre l’austerità (beyond austerity),
E-boo k pu blished in Micromeg a on-line.
Diamond, J. (2006). Guns, germs, and steel. The fates of human socie-
ties. New York: W. W. Norton & Comp any.
Forges Davanzati, G. (2013). Le pol iti ch e di au s ter it à: Un’Analisi criti-
ca (Austerity policies: A cr i tical anal ysis). MarxXXI.
www.marx21.it
Forges Davanzati, G., & Paolilli , A. L. (200 4 ). Alt ru i sm o, s cam bi e svi -
luppo economico (Altruism, trade and economic development). In L.
Tundo Ferente (Ed.), La responsabilità del pensare (The responsi-
bility of thought) (pp. 289-307 ). Naples: Liguori Editore.
Glaeser, E. L., & Shleifer, A. (2002) . The Injustice of Inequality, NBER
Working Papers 9150. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
Glaeser, E. L., Scheinkman, J., & Shleifer, A. (2003). The injustice of in-
equality, Journal of Monetary Economics, 50, 19 9-222.
http://dx.d oi.org/10.1016/S0304-3932(02)00204 -0
Krugman, P. R. (1991). Increasing returns and economic geography. The
Journal of Political Economy, 99 , 483-499.
http://dx.d oi.org/10.1086/261763
Krugman, P. R. (1998). What’s new about the New Economic Geogra-
phy”. Journal of Political Economy, 14, 7-17.
Mandelbrot, B. (1963). The variation of certain speculative prices.
Journal of Business, 36, 394-419. htt p://dx.doi.org/10.1086/ 294632
Martinez Oliva, J. C. (2009). Riun i f icazi on e i nt er t ed esc a e p oli t ich e p er
la convergenza (Inter-German reunification and convergence polici-
es), Questioni di Economia e Finanza (Occas ional pape rs) (Issues of
economics and finance (Occasional papers)), Banca d’Italia, 51.
Myrdal, K. G. (1957). Economic theory and under-developed regions.
London : Gerald Duckworth.
Paolilli, A. L. (2008). Development and crisis in ancient Rome: The
role of Medit erranean trade. Histo rical Soci al Resea rch. An Intern a-
tional Journal for the Application of Formal Methods to History, 33 ,
274-289.
Paolilli, A. L. (2011). Div ari econ omici t errito riali e proces si di fin an-
ziarizzazione delleconomia. Il caso del Mezzogiorno nello scenario
europeo del dopo Maastricht (Territorial economic disparity and pro-
cesses of financing of the economy. The Mezzogiorno in the post-
Maastricht European scenario). PhD Thesis, Lecce: Salento Univer-
sity.
Paolilli, A. L. (2011). Altruism, selfishness and social cohesion. Socio-
logy M ind, 1, 145-150 .
Paolilli, A. L., & Pollice, F. (2011). Trajectories of state formation in
Eurasia: A di scu ssion. Historical Social Research. An International
Journal for the Application of Formal Methods to History, 36, 343-
371.
Paolilli, A. L., & Pollic e, F. (2 011 ). Finance and centre-periphery dyna-
mics: A model. iBusiness, 3, 248-261.
http://dx.d oi.org/10.4236/s m .2011.14018
Scheidel, W. (2007). The First Great Divergence: Trajectories of post-
ancient forma tion in eas tern an d western E uras ia. P r inceton/ Stanford:
Working Papers in Classics.
Spratt, S. (2009). Development finance, debates, dogmas and new direc-
tions. London and New York: Routle dge.
Vita, C. (2006-2007). Economie dualistiche e processi cumulativi di
divergenza. Il dibattito sui Mezzogiorni dEuro pa (Dualistic econo-
mies and cumulative processes of divergence. The debate on Eu-
rope’s South). PhD Thes is, B enev ento: Sannio University.
OPEN ACCE SS
50