Theoretical Economics Letters, 2012, 2, 395-399
http://dx.doi.org/10.4236/tel.2012.24073 Published Online October 2012 (http://www.SciRP.org/journal/tel)
A Microeconomic Foundation for Optimum Currency
Areas: The Case for Perfect Capital Mobility and
Immobile Labor Forc es
Masayuki Otaki
Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo, Tokyo, Japan
Email: ohtaki@iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp
Received June 6, 2012; revised July 2, 2012; accepted August 1, 2012
ABSTRACT
This article provides a microeconomic foundation for Mundell’s optimum currency area theory. We consider twin
countries where labor forces are fixed to each country although the real capital moves internationally. When the central
bank in each country behaves non-cooperatively, it will raise the domestic interest rate to attract more real capital and
increase the rent of her residences. However, the fierce competition between the central banks ultimately exacerbates
the disparity in income distribution. Moreover, when the real capital or the financial intermediary as its agent does not
have a nationality, the worsened income distribution also results in the inefficient resource allocation. Thus, such twin
countries should unify their central banks and coordinate their monetary and interest policies. In other words, these
countries constitute an optimum currency area.
Keywords: Optimum Currency Area; Capital without a Nationality; Non-Cooperative Game between Central Banks;
Disparity in income Distribution; Inefficiency of Resource Allocation
1. Introduction
Income disparity is not limited to developing countries.
Advanced economies also face this growing problem.
This article considers why such an undesirable economic
consequence is invoked when constructing a microeco-
nomic foundation for the optimum currency area theory
originating from Mundell’s [1] seminal work.
As Mundell [1] emphasizes, the mobility of production
resources plays a crucial role when we consider which
economies should constitute an optimum currency area.
We deal with the case in which both labor forces are
immobile and have a nationality but real capital with no
nationality can move internationally at the owners’ or
their agents’ (banks, security companies and etc. ) discre-
tion. Such a setting is plausible when we observe that
foreign direct investment is generally preferable to certi-
fying work visas.
When small twin countries with identical economic
structure are in this situation, their central banks compete
to invite more real capitals to enrich their economy as
long as the countries attain full employment. Nonetheless,
such competition has the following devastating cones-
quence.
If one central bank pursues a high-interest policy to at-
tract more real capital, the other central bank counterof-
fers with a higher interest rate. Such a cumulative proc-
ess does not cease until a surplus from working that is the
benefits of the high interest policy vanish entirely.
Consequently, the non-cooperative behavior of two
central banks brings about a serious income disparity be-
tween capital and labor. Furthermore, since capitals or
financial intermediaries as their agents are assumed to
have no nationality, the emerging disparity also results in
the large welfare losses for these two nations.
The unification of two central banks is desirable for
overcoming such a difficulty. The small twin countries
should be at least economically integrated. Then, the
same amount of money is supplied to ensure full em-
ployment and the interest rates offered to non-nationality
real capitals become identical at the lowest level.
Accordingly, each country is supplied with an amount
of real capital, and thus, the income disparity and ineffi-
cient resource allocation within the nations are entirely
resolved. That is, the small twin countries constitute an
optimum currency area whenever the real capital mobil-
ity is complete.
The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. In
Section 2, we construct a small twin country model based
on Otaki [2]. In Section 3, we compare the non-coopera-
tive and cooperative monetary policies, and prove the
inevitability of optimum currency areas. In Section 4, we
C
opyright © 2012 SciRes. TEL
M. OTAKI
396
summarize the analyses and results. In Section 5, we pro-
vide brief concluding remarks.
2. The Model
2.1. Structure of the Model
We use a two-period overlapping generation model in a
production economy with money. The world consists of
twin countries A and B, whose economic structures are
identical, and the rest of the world. Each country has re-
sidents who cannot move elsewhere and who live in two
periods with the density [0, 1].
Each resident specializes in producing one differenti-
ated goods with the help of real capitals when he/she is
young. Real capital, whose owners have no nationality,
exists with the density [0,1] [0,2]
. Hence, each resi-
dent can potentially deploy the real capitals with the den-
sity [0, 1]. Capital income is also earned when the owner
is young, and then capital itself is passed to a descendant.
Once an owner determines the location of his/her capital,
he/she lives in that country even after his retirement. The
minimum rate of return from the rest of the world () is
guaranteed to all capital owners. Furthermore, for sim-
plicity, a unit real capital combined with a resident’s
business skills produces a unit good.
r
The income distribution between residents and capital
owners is determined by a negotiation. The negotiation
process, which was developed by Otaki [2], is assumed
to be the following two-stage game. First, a resident de-
termines how much capital to deploy in order to maxi-
mize his/her income from business skills. Second, given
the volume of capital deployed and goods produced, the
residents and owners mutually determine the income dis-
tribution in accordance with the asymmetric Nash bar-
gaining solution.
In addition, there is a central bank in each country,
which pursues the social welfare of her residents. Each
central bank’s policy variables are the nominal money
supply and the real interest rate (i.e., the rate of return for
capital). We assume that a central bank manipulates the
real interest rate by intervening in the negotiation process
between her residents and the non-nationality capital
owners or financial intermediaries that are agents of capi-
tal owners. That is, a central bank can control the bar-
gaining power of her residents through moral suasion.
2.2. Construction of the Model
2.2.1. Individual’s Utility and Consumption Functions
We assume that all individuals (including capital owners)
have the same concave and linear homogenous lifetime
function:


1
1
1
11
1
1, 20
,d
ii
Uuccccz z






,
where
i
cz is the consumption of good z during the
ith stage of life. We can derive the following corre-
sponding indirect utility function
I
U:


1
1
,,
,1,
ttt
t
ttt t
YyY
IU y
ppp p

,
t
p
(1)
where t is the nominal income and is the price
index defined by
Yt
p

1
11
1
0d
tt
ppzz


.
Furthermore, the consumption function of the younger
generation C is

t
Cc y
. (2)
Finally, the demand function for good z is
 
d
pz
Dz y
p


, (3)
where is the aggregate demand.
d
y
2.2.2. Production Process by the Two-Stage Game
To develop the aforementioned production process, we
consider the following two-stage game.
1) Each resident maximizes his/her income from busi-
ness skills by deploying non-nationality capitals;
2) The resident and capital owners or financial inter-
mediaries negotiate their income distribution in accor-
dance with the asymmetric Nash bargaining solution the
threaten point of which is *
0, r
We must solve this problem by backward induction. In
the second stage game, the corresponding generalized
Nash product
.
,Gzi is
 
1
*
,ii
ii
GPz ipzrrr

 



, (4)
where
is the degree of toleran ce, that is, residents’
discount rate applied to the negotiation process with cap-
ital owners or their agents1. i
i is the modified (ac-
tual) discount rate; that is,
denotes the power of
moral suasion of i country’s central bank to decrease the
residents’ discount rate to induce more capital rapidly
into the domestic economy. is the domestic rate of
return for a unit capital.
i
r
The shape of the product is derived from two proper-
ties of the model. First, the objective function is linear on
the real income as indicated by (1). Second, the produc-
tion (or demand) volume is already determined by the
first stage of the game.
Maximizing (4) with respect to , we obtain the equi-
librium domestic rate of return :
i
r
*i
r

*1
ii
rpz
 
i
r

 

. (5)
1See Rubinstein [3] for a detail interpretation concerning the asymmet-
ric Nash bar
g
ainin
g
solution.
Copyright © 2012 SciRes. TEL
M. OTAKI 397
Taking (5) into consideration, the maximization prob-
lem of the first stage can be expressed as


 

 
*
πmax
max
ii
pz
ipz
zpzrDz
p
zrDz





 


(6)
The solution to (6) is

*
1,.
1
r
pz z
(7)
Hence, the price level p is constant over time and the
equilibrium inflation rate is . Substituting (3) and
(7) into (6), we obtain
*1

1
*
π
,
ii
zy
p




d
i
(8)
where di
y
denotes the real GDP of country i. From (1),
it is clear that (8) corresponds to the social welfare of re-
sidents in country i.
2.2.3. The Market Equilibrium
In both countries, money is supplied through the unex-
pected transfer to the older generation; thus, taking (2)
into consideration, the equilibrium condition for the do-
mestic aggregate goods market becomes
 
1
11
i
didi idim
ycymyc

,
i
j
(9)
where denotes the real money supply within country
i. The second term of (9) corresponds to the aggregate
expenditure of the older generation.
i
m
Owing to the perfect mobility, the real capital market
achieves equilibrium when
2, >
=1, =
0, <
ij
i
ij
if
kif
if
(10)
where is the amount of capital that has been invested
in country i.
i
k
The model contains five types of endogenous variable
**
,,π,,
iidi
rp yk

,
ii
m
i
, two types of exogenous variable
, and five structural Equations (5) and (7)-(10).
Thus, the model is closed.
2.3. The Non-Cooperative Game between
Central Banks and the Disparity in Income
Distribution
Because of the international mobility of real capitals and
the representation of social welfare (8), each central bank
is eager to attract more capital and enrich its country.
Such competition is described by the following two-stage
game. In the first stage, central banks determine (,)
AB
.
Next, they decide how much money they supply (i.e.,
).
(,
AB
mm)
i
j
To solve the equilibrium of this game, we must begin
with the second stage. Since the outcomes of the first
stage are summarized by (10), taking the social welfare
(8) and the equilibrium condition for each aggregated
goods market (9) into consideration, the best response of
each central bank is to maintain the full-employment
equilibrium, which is defined as the amount of real capi-
tal that is associated with its country. Hence, the follow-
ing dominant strategy in this game corresponds to the
result of the first-stage game. That is,
2, >
=1, =.
0, <
ij
i
ij
if
mif
if
(11)
Since full-employment is assured in the second stage,
central banks strive to invite as much real capital as pos-
sible. The following theorem holds concerning the unique-
ness of the Nash equilibrium:
Theorem 1.
The unique Nash equilibrium is characterized by
*
**
*
π
,, 1,,0
i
ii
mp



(12)
Proof.
<Sufficiency> If (12) is satisfied, there is no active
incentive to diverge the strategies because no additional
gain is obtained by lesser
**
,
ii
m
. Hence, (12) is a
Nash equilibrium.
<Necessity> Suppose that
*i
*
π
p is strictly positive in
some Nash equilibrium. Then,
**
**
**
ππ
ij ij
pp
.
By selecting a **
j
slightly larger than *i
, country
improves her social welfare as much as
j
**1 0.
j
 


Thus, there is an incentive to diverge from the equilib-
rium. This is a contradiction.
The economic implication of Theorem 1 is quite seri-
ous. As long as two central banks extend the non-coop-
erative game to attract more capital, the income disparity
deepens against their intentions. Owing to the competi-
tion, residents’ earnings from business skills are utterly
absorbed by the capital income. Since, as seen in (8), the
social welfare of residents is proportional to their income,
the deepening income disparity also results in a less effi-
cient economy.
Such a phenomenon is prominent in East Asia, for ex-
ample. In this area, foreign direct investments flow mainly
from Japan and China to other countries. Although the
capital accumulation sufficiently advances and a limited
Copyright © 2012 SciRes. TEL
M. OTAKI
398
number of capitalists and banks surprisingly become rich,
the labor income of most residents including those in Ja-
pan and China stagnates. Income disparity is one of the
most urgent problems in East Asia.
3. The Optimum Currency Area as the
Unification of Central Banks
In the previous section, we showed that the non-cooperative
actions of central banks have quite harmful effects on
both countries. In this sense, we propose the unification
of central banks. According to Mundell [1], a currency
area is defined as follows:
“A single currency implies a single central bank (with
note-issuing power) and therefore a potentially elastic
supply of interregional means of payment.” (p. 568)
We adopt this definition of a currency area.
When central banks are unified and a currency area is
formed, the twin countries, A and B, can be treated as a
single country, and hence, monetary coordination becomes
possible. Because of the symmetry of the countries, the
optimal coordination policy is also symmetric. Hence the
two-step game extended in 2.3 requires equal allocation
of real capital. Thus, we obtain and
It is evident that the social welfare of each
country (8) becomes
1
AB
mm
0.
AB


1
. This is the maximal value
that each country attains. In this sense, these twin coun-
tries together constitute an optimum currency area2.
4. Results and Analyses
We reconsider the theory of optimum currency area from
the perspective of resource allocation and income distri-
bution. The obtained results are as follows.
We concentrate on the case of twin countries under per-
fect capital mobility and immobile labor forces. This as-
sumption seems natural if we consider the significance of
the existence of nation states.
When each central bank pursues its national interests,
that is, the social welfare of its immobile labor force (i.e.,
the residents), dire economic consequences emerge. Each
central bank is led to adopt an artificial high interest pol-
icy because more capital induced by a rate slightly higher
than the rates of its rival central bank brings about higher
incomes for the business skills possessed by the residents
of that central bank’s nation. However, such competitive
and escalating interest-raising is devastating and cumula-
tive, and it does not end until all the residents’ income is
absorbed by the real capital without nationality. Thus, a
serious income disparity and a large decrease in social
welfare occur. It is clear that the nation is not an opti-
mum currency area.
When the two central banks are unified and the mone-
tary coordination becomes possible, such catastrophic
competition ceases. Real capital is allocated equally by
abolishing the competitive and artificial high-interest pol-
icy. Just enough external money is supplied to ensure the
full-employment equilibrium in each country. Thus, the
social welfare achieves its maximum. In other words, our
twin countries under perfect capital mobility constitute
an optimum currency area. It is also noteworthy that our
approach is based on a rigorous dynamic microeconomic
foundation, and thus, enables the economic welfare analy-
sis. In this sense, we succeed in updating and extending
the theory of Mundell [1]3.
5. Concluding Remarks
We obtain the result that twin-countries with perfect cap-
ital mobility should form a currency area in the sense of
Mundell [1].
We must note some limitation of our work. The first is
the difficulty of central bank unification. Bureaucrats
who operate the unified central bank may be of different
nationalities. Differences due to culture, ethnicity, tradi-
tion, and etc., are not as easy to overcome as our theory
assumes. It takes more time than we expect to ensure fare
policy coordination. As Hamada [5] argues, in general,
any monetary integration cannot works well without ac-
complishing political integration beforehand, at least
historically.
The second concerns the glut of foreign direct invest-
ment. In reality, the volume and range of mobile real
capital is large and wide. It is feared that the world as a
whole may become a unique optimum currency area.
Nevertheless, it is certain that such a tremendous and
enlarged organization would never work well. It may be
more practical to place a levy on international capital
movement, like the Tobin tax.
REFERENCES
2Hamada [4] and [5] also analyze not only how past monetary integra-
tions were generated but also what policies were desirable to sustain
such union, although his models are basically static and find difficulty
in expressing functions of money explicitly.
3Casella [6] analyses the utility of monetary union as the saving o
f
transaction costs. However, the substance of such costs is not necessar-
ily clear. Although Basevi, Delbono, and Delnicolo [7] argue that there
are microeconomic benefits from the monetary integration, they do no
t
find the existence of the fierce zero-sum game between the central
banks that we deal here. That is, both studies do not directly connect
with the theoretical relationship between factor mobility and the neces-
sity of a currency area that is the most serious concern of Mundell [1].
[1] R. A. Mundell, “A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas,”
American Economic Review, Vol. 51, No. 4, 1961, pp. 657-
665.
[2] M. Otaki, “A Welfare Economics Foundation for the Full-
Employment Policy,” Economics Letters, Vol. 102, No. 1,
2009, pp. 1-3. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2008.08.003
[3] A. Rubinstein, “Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model,”
Econometrica, Vol. 50, No. 1, 1982, pp. 97-110.
doi:10.2307/1912531
Copyright © 2012 SciRes. TEL
M. OTAKI
Copyright © 2012 SciRes. TEL
399
[4] K. Hamada, “On the Political Economy of Monetary Inte-
gration,” In: R. Z. Aliber, Ed., National Monetary Poli-
cies and the International Financial System, University of
Chicago Press, Chicago, 1974.
[5] K. Hamada, “On the Coordination of Monetary Policies
in a Monetary Union,” Paper Presented at the Col loquium
on New Economic Approach to the Study of International
Integration, European University Institute, 1979.
[6] A. Cassella, “Participation in a Monetary Union,” Ameri-
can Economic Review, Vol. 82, No. 4, 1992, pp. 847-863.
[7] G. Besevi, F. Delbono and V. Delnicolo, “International
Monetary Cooperation and Economic Influence,” Journal
of International Economics, Vol. 28, 1990, pp. 1-23.