Theoretical Economics Letters
Vol. 2  No. 2 (2012) , Article ID: 19330 , 4 pages DOI:10.4236/tel.2012.22041

Revisiting the Effects of Economic Incentives on Motivation

Kameliia Petrova

Department of Economics and Finance, State University of New York, Plattsburgh, USA

Email: kpetr001@plattsburgh.edu

Received March 7, 2012; revised April 5, 2012; accepted April 10, 2012

Keywords: Incentives; Intrinsic Motivation; Non-Additive Probability

ABSTRACT

This paper presents a formal framework for modeling the effects of economic incentives on motivation. While economic models represent the utilities from monetary incentives and private benefits in an additive form, studies in psychology show that extrinsic and intrinsic motivation are non-additive and that there exists a continuum between the two. To accommodate for possible interaction effects, a non-additive probability model and evidence theory have been used in the principal-agent set-up. The model produces results consistent with prior evidence presented in social psychology studies.

1. Introduction

The interactions between economic incentives and intrinsic motivation have been widely documented in economics literature (see, for example, [1] and more recently [2] for surveys). Similarly, in social psychology, there is a vast amount of literature exploring the effect of rewards on intrinsic motivation ([3-5]). The main evidential claim presented is that, under certain conditions, monetary rewards decrease intrinsic motivation, and this may result in reduction of the activity or performance. This premise is based on the underlying assumption that every activity indeed has intrinsic motivation. Commonly accepted are two theoretical explanations: self-perception theory and cognitive evaluation theory [6]. The selfperception theory postulates that individuals do not have information about their own motives ([7,8]). Instead, they have to infer them from the circumstances under which the activity takes place. One representation of this idea is [9], who uses a simple informed-principal model to show how an agent, uncertain about his abilities, deduces his motives through the signaling mechanism. The agent interprets given reward as a signal of having low ability or as one of an unattractive task being proposed. In the absence of rewards he assigns the motives of performing to his intrinsic motivation. The cognitive evaluation theory [5] assumes that people have psychological needs for self-determination, competence and autonomy. It is the effect of rewards on these three elements that matters. When rewards are perceived as controlling, there is a negative effect on self-determination and autonomy. Hence, intrinsic motivation is undermined. Conversely, when rewards have an informational role (feedback, recognition etc.) they enhance intrinsic motivation by affecting the individual’s competence. The cognitive evaluation theory has more recently been generalized into the self-determination theory [10] which allows for a continuum between intrinsic and extrinsic motivation.

This paper offers a novel approach to model the effect of economic incentives on motivation as it is related to self-determination, autonomy and competence in cognitive evaluation theory by employing a subjective probability concept. To be able to use this set-up one more change must be made. Most economics studies represent the utilities from monetary incentives and private benefits in an additive form. In psychological literature extrinsic and intrinsic motivation are non-additive, but exhibit some form of interrelation and form a continuum ([5,10]). This paper will extend the formal set-up by employing a non-additive probability model, which allows the capturing of effects from interaction. At the same time this can be viewed more generally as an extension of the standard economic model of worker’s motivation.

2. Subjective Probability Model

Consider the following non-additive probability model1:

(1)

where x is a vector of extrinsic rewards, y is a vector of intrinsic rewards, is the probability level of total motivation (resulting from extrinsic and intrinsic factors), is the probability level of intrinsic motivation, is the probability level of extrinsic motivation, and λ is a coefficient representing the degree of influence of the interaction between intrinsic and extrinsic rewards on the total motivation2. This model can be interpreted as follows: The total level of motivation is affected either extrinsically via some extrinsic reward x or intrinsically via some intrinsic reward y, or to some extent λ by the mutual interaction between x and y. Formally, this is a representation of the idea coming from psychology literature that extrinsic and intrinsic motivetion are non-additive, but exhibit some form of interacttion [10]. On the other hand, this can be viewed as an extension of the standard economic model of worker’s motivation which allows for a more comprehensive description of motivation, including the concept of intrinsic motivation. In the light of a principal-agent model, the following notations are used:

• The principal’s assessment of the total probability is. This is a subjective probability which represents how certain the principal (she) is about the agent’s motivation.

• The agent (he) has his own assessment of,. It is assumed that. The case when is analyzed later on. is also subjective and uncertain to some extent.

• The assumption is made that when the principal selects an extrinsic reward scheme she is able to calculate. The same concerns the agent, i.e. his probability level with respect to particular extrinsic reward scheme is.

• The influence parameter λ is positive and λ ∈ [0, 1], where λ = 0 means that there is no interaction between extrinsic and intrinsic incentive schemes, but λ = 1 means strict interaction.

The principal forms and selects a relative policy, neither knowing the precise value of nor how this policy will affect. This paper discusses policy as opposed to a simple incentive scheme since y* as an element of this policy is not strictly defined. Choosing x* corresponds to the preparation of an incentive scheme in the standard principle-agent model. The new element here is how y* is taken into consideration to enable choice of the optimal x* regarding the agent’s real motivation. Note that when there is no intrinsic motivation; this results in

bringing the model back to the standard incentive model. The principal’s goal is to stimulate the agent’s initiative and intrinsic motivation through a proper combination of x* and a particular set-up of p which results in y*.

3. Aggregation of and

This section explores the uncertainty brought by introducing intrinsic motivation. For reasons that will be detailed later in this paper, a method to aggregate and must be developed. Both and are overor underestimated. Wh le can be measured relative to its argument x* and any possible overor underestimation recovered, a similar measure cannot be achieved with respect to the pair and. These two probabilities are dependent on the incentive scheme y* which is non-measurable. The uncertainty through and is thus higher in comparison to. They are more subjective. To derive an expression for the aggregation of and the evidence theory and the principle of maximum non-specificity ([11,12]) are used.

Let us consider a finite set of task-specific intrinsic motivators X. From this set, three subsets are of interest: the set A of intrinsic motivators which the principal considers as active with respect to incentive scheme y*; the set B of intrinsic motivators which the agent considers as active with respect to the incentive scheme y*, and the set which is treated as an intersection between the active intrinsic motivators relative to the opinion of both the agent and the principal. In this sense a particular incentive scheme is optimal when. The subsets A and B are claimed for a particular y* to degrees and respectively. Those degrees represent the total beliefs that put the attention on A and B. The aim now is to estimate the belief of relative to the incentive scheme y* using the principle of maximum non-specificity. This principle is a safeguard that does not allow us to produce an answer that is more specific than warranted by the evidence, i.e. and. The use of the principle of maximum non-specificity leads, in this case, to the following optimization problem ([11,13]): determine the values of and for which the function:

(2)

reaches its maximum when subjected to the following constraints:

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

where and represents the cardinality of the subset. The function N describes nonspecificity in evidence theory and is considered a generalized measure of uncertainty. In general, for arbitrary element indicates the degree of evidence focusing on, while indicates the lack of specificity of this evidential claim. The larger the value of, the stronger the evidence; the larger the set (and), the less specific the evidence. The total beliefs and assess not only and, but as well. This corresponds to the premise that both the principal and the agent forecast not only their own, but also the degree to which their claim coincides with the claim of the opponent player, i.e.. The constraints are represented with three linear algebraic equations of four unknowns and by the requirement that the unknowns be nonnegative and real. The first two equations represent the evidence relative to the principal and to the agent respectively; the third inequality represents a general constraint in evidence theory. After selecting as an independent variable, the following is obtained

(7)

(8)

(9)

Since all unknowns must be nonnegative, from the first two equations one can evaluate the upper bound for. Further, from

(10)

(11)

it follows that

(12)

The third equation with respect to specifies the lower bound of. Indeed, for it follows that:

(13)

(14)

If then

(15)

But should be nonnegative, hence for the lower bound it follows that

(16)

The bounds, thus, are

(17)

Using Equations (7)-(9), the objective function N now can be expressed in terms of. After some rearrangements and simplification the result is

(18)

It is clear that only the first term in this expression can influence the value of the objective function, so it can be rewritten as

(19)

where

(20)

and

(21)

are constants. The solution of the optimization problem depends only on the value of K1. The assumption is made that A, B, and are non-empty subsets in X and thus. If then and the maximum of N is attained after minimization of, i.e., and attains a minimum equal to its lower bound. If then and must maximize , i.e.. When, , and thus N is independent of. This implies that every value in the interval is a solution of the optimization problem. The complete solution for relative to y can thus be expressed by the following equations:

(22)

where is the associated degree of belief.

4. Model Problem

The following model refers to the principal

(23)

What happens to the agent? The agent needs to have his participation and incentive compatibility constraints satisfied. This results in known A and, but uncertain and λ. Where is defined in the sense of Equation (22). Hence, the agent behaves with respect to the following model:

(24)

In general, we can use the following system to describe the principal-agent relationship:

(25)

(26)

In this system the unknown are and λ. Solving the system gives us:

(27)

and

(28)

Let us investigate how is affected by the extrinsic rewards vector. This means to investigate the first derivative of with respect to P. The latter is

(29)

Clearly A is positive and hence the sign of depends on the sign of. The following two cases can be considered:

1), with a possible interpretation that the extrinsic reward policy employs controlling effect, and this is a signal for the agent which decreases his intrinsic motivation, i.e.

(30)

2), with a possible interpretation that the extrinsic reward policy plays an informational role, which increases the agent’s intrinsic motivation, i.e.

(31)

5. Conclusion

This paper proposes a novel approach to model the effect of economic incentives on motivation by employing subjective probability concept. While economic models represent the utilities from monetary incentives and private benefits in an additive form, studies in psychology show that extrinsic and intrinsic motivation are non-additive and that there exists a continuum between the two. The proposal of this paper is to extend the formal set-up by employing a non-additive probability model, which allows capturing the effects from interaction. The model produces results consistent with the evidence in social psychology studies.

REFERENCES

  1. B. Frey and R. Jegen, “Motivation Crowding Theory,” Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 15, No. 5, 2001, pp. 589-611. doi:10.1111/1467-6419.00150
  2. A. Festré, “Incentives and Social Norms: A Motivation-Based Economic Analysis of Social Norms,” Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 24, No. 3, 2009, pp. 511-538. doi:10.1111/j.1467-6419.2009.00594.x
  3. E. Deci, “Effects of Externally Mediated Rewards on Intrinsic Motivation,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, Vol. 18, No. 1, 1971, pp. 105-115. doi:10.1037/h0030644
  4. E. Deci and R. Ryan, “Intrinsic Motivation and Self-Determination in Human Behavior,” Plenum, New York, 1985.
  5. E. Deci, R. Koestner and R. Ryan, “A Meta-Analytic Review of Experiments Examining the Effects of Extrinsic Rewards on Intrinsic Motivation,” Psychological Bulletin, Vol. 125, No. 6, 1999, pp. 627-668. doi:10.1037/0033-2909.125.6.627
  6. E. Fehr and A. Falk, “Psychological Foundations of Incentives,” European Economic Review, Vol. 46, No. 4-5, 2002, pp. 687-724. doi:10.1016/S0014-2921(01)00208-2
  7. D. Bem, “Self-Perception: The Dependent Variable of Human Performance,” Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, Vol. 2, No. 2, 1967, pp. 105-121. doi:10.1016/0030-5073(67)90025-6
  8. D. Bem, “Self-Perception Theory,” In: L. Berkowitz, Ed., Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, Academic Press, New-York, Vol. 6, 1972.
  9. R. Benabou and J. Tirol, “Self-Confidence and Personal Motivation,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117, No. 3, 2002, pp. 871-916. doi:10.1162/003355302760193913
  10. M. Gagne and E. Deci, “Self-Determination Theory and Work Motivation,” Journal of Organizational Behavior, Vol. 26, No. 4, 2005, pp. 331-362. doi:10.1002/job.322
  11. D. Dubois and A. Prade, “A Note on Measures of Specificity for Fuzzy Sets,” International Journal of General Systems, Vol. 10, No. 4, 1985, pp. 279-283. doi:10.1080/03081078508934893
  12. G. Klir, “Principles of Uncertainty: What Are They? Why We Need Them?” Fuzzy Sets and Systems, Vol. 74, No. 1, 1995, pp. 15-31. doi:10.1016/0165-0114(95)00032-G
  13. D. Dubois and A. Prade, “The Principle of Minimum Specificity as a Basis for Evidential Reasoning,” In: B. Bouchon-Minier and R. Yager, Eds., Uncertainty in Knowledge-Based Systems, Springer, New-York, 1987.

NOTES

1The main feature of subjective probability is that it recovers the intuitive concept of probability as a degree of belief. In contrast to the standard theory, these beliefs can be represented by non-additive probabilities.

2x is defined in the sense of standard incentive schemes, while y can be interpreted as the subjective intrinsic reward from performing a particular task. Due to its nature, Pi(y) cannot be formally measured. However, a proxy can be constructed to give us an approximation of the degree of an agent’s intrinsic motivation.