Journal of Mathematical Finance
Vol.05 No.02(2015), Article ID:56555,9 pages
10.4236/jmf.2015.52018

Duopolistic Competition and Capacity Choice with Jump-Diffusion Process

Danmei Chen1,2

1School of Finance, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, Shanghai, China

2Basic Department, Shanghai Jianqiao University, Shanghai, China

Email: chenccc_008@163.com

Copyright © 2015 by author and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution International License (CC BY).

http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/

Received 12 April 2015; accepted 17 May 2015; published 22 May 2015

ABSTRACT

This paper studies the effects of sudden events on the optimal timing and capacity choice in a duopoly market. According to the characteristics of economic environment, we assume that the product demand follows geometric Brownian motion with a Poisson jump process. Under the settings, the firms face the risk of a sudden drop in demand which is caused by sudden events. We develop the real option game model to derive the investment equilibrium strategies. Moreover, the effects of sudden events on investment decisions are obtained by numerical analysis.

Keywords:

Investment Decisions, Competitive, Real Option Game, Jump-Diffusion Process

1. Introduction

We develop the real option game model to discuss the effects of sudden events on the optimal timing and capacity choice in a duopoly market. When sudden events occur, such as the financial crisis, economic policy from government, and the emergence of new products, discontinuous change in product demand appears. We use jump- diffusion process to capture the discontinuous changes of product demand.

Most real option game models suppose that the uncertainty variables such as asset price or product demand follow the geometric Brown motion (GBM) to describe the characteristics of continuous changes (e.g. Smets [1] ; Dixit and Pindyck [2] ; Grenadier [3] ; Weeds [4] ; Mason and Weeds [5] ).

However, the GBM cannot explain some important empirical features of asset price or product demand dynamics. Jorion [6] and Bates [7] discovered the presence of jumps in asset price through empirical research. Recent studies have pointed out the importance of allowing for jumps, or discontinuities of asset price or product demand due to the effects of random sudden events in the economic environment. Merton [8] assumed that the stock price follows a jump-diffusion process with Poisson jump to model sudden events. Kou [9] proposed a double exponential jump-diffusion model. Mason and Wilmot [10] investigated the potential presence of jumps in natural gas price. Ko et al. [11] established real option game model with jump process to investigate the effects of sudden events on investment timing. Pereira and Armada [12] assumed that the entrance of the hidden rivals follows a Poisson process. The project value of the positioned firm has a sudden drop as the hidden rivals enter the market. They presented a model suitable for investment decisions under a hidden competition environment. Pereira and Rodrigues [13] assumed that firms face the risk of demonopolization from government that can occur as a random or a certain event. They studied the optimal timing in finite-lived monopolies.

The large majority of real option game models focus on the investment timing without considering production capacity choice. However, in reality, production capacity decision is a key factor when one firm invests products. Few studies have considered the interaction between the investment timing and the production capacity in a real option framework. Besanko et al. [14] considered the investment decisions of the heterogeneous products under discrete time framework. Jou and Lee [15] assumed that all firms use the same investment strategy, obtaining the investment timing and the optimal capacity under imperfect competition. Huisman and Kort [16] provided a dynamic analysis of entry deterrence strategies, they discovered the leader overinvest in capacity in order to delay entry of the follower. The paper has close connection with these studies, which are extended by introducing the effects of sudden events and pre-emptive competition on the investment decisions. In this model, two firms are allowed to produce the homogeneous products; the product demand is assumed to obey the geometric Brown motion with a Poisson jump process. We discuss strategic investment decisions under duopolistic competition.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the basic assumption of the real option game model. In Section 3, we derive the equilibrium strategies in a duopoly market. Section 4 exercises numerical analysis. Section 5 concludes the paper.

2. Basic Assumption of Real Option Game Model

In the section, we assume two firms have the chance to produce the homogeneous products in a duopoly market. Time is continuous and horizon is infinite. So every firm can defer the investment timing until the optimal moment to enter the market. The firm that enters first is known as the leader and the other as the follower. The product price at time t in market is given as follows:

(1)

where is the exogenous demand shock, Q is the total market output, unit production cost is c, so the total costs of production are cQ. Similar to Huisman and Kort [16] , every firm cannot adjust production capacity after entering the market and the two firms must make full use of production capacity. The exogenous demand shock is affected by sudden events of external market environment. Suppose that obey the geometric Brown motion with the Poisson jump process:

Among the above factors, represents the drift rate, represents the volatility, is the increment of a standard Brownian motion. We assume to ensure that the option is exercised within a finite period of time. We assume random sudden events follow the Poisson jump process of intensity. This means sudden events occur with probability during the time interval dt. Sudden drop in product demand as the events occur. represents the deterministic amplitude of the downward jumps satisfying. Assume and are independent, so:

3. Investment Decisions in a Duopoly Market

In the section, we develop the model to determine the values and the investment decisions of two firms in a duopoly market, facing the risk of random sudden drop in product demand.

3.1. The Follower’s Value Function

We need to consider the game backwards. When the leader has invested the project, the follower can make his decisions optimally in response to capacity of the leader. Suppose that the leader has invested the project with capacity ql, the investment threshold and capacity of the follower are chosen as Xf and qf, so the investment costs are. The value function of the follower is recorded as for short. By using the standard real option method, the Bellman equation can be expressed as:

According to Itô’s Lemma, the value of the follower satisfies the following differential equation:

(2)

The general solution of (1) is of the form:

(3)

Among them, , are the undetermined coefficients, , are the roots of the equation

:

Moreover, the value of the follower must satisfy three boundary conditions:

(4)

(5)

(6)

Condition (4) says that the value will be 0 if. Condition (5) and (6) are the value-matching and the smooth-pasting conditions. The two conditions ensure that can be maximized when the firm invests at the threshold.

Under these conditions, the value, the investment threshold and capacity of the follower are calculated as follows:

(7)

where

(8)

(9)

We assume that the initial demand level is sufficiently low, the follower will not start production immediately. According to (7), the value of the follower:

(10)

See from (10), is function of. We apply (8), (9) to (10), the follower considers the capacity to maximize the value, satisfies the first order condition:

(11)

Combining (8) and (11), we obtain the optimal threshold and the capacity of the follower:

(12)

Substitute (12) into (9) and (10), the value of the follower is as follows:

(13)

Let in (12), the optimal threshold and the capacity of the monopolist are as follows:

(14)

3.2. The Leader’s Value Function

When the follower is out of the market, the leader earns profits at time t. When the follower en-

ters the market, the leader’s profits decreases to at time t. Suppose that the value function of

the leader is. is also written as for simplicity. Let, so represent that the value subtract the investment costs when the leader has invested. satisfies the following differential equation:

(15)

The general solution of (15) is of the form:

(16)

The value of the leader must satisfy two boundary conditions:

(17)

(18)

If we apply (17), (18) to (16), is given by:

(19)

where

(20)

Before the leader invests the project, the value of the leader satisfies the following differential equation:

(21)

The general solution of (21) is of the form:

(22)

In addition, the value of the leader must satisfy three boundary conditions:

(23)

(24)

(25)

Condition (24) says that:

(26)

If we apply (23), (24), (25) to (22), we obtain:

(27)

where

(28)

(29)

We assume that the initial demand level is sufficiently low, the leader will not start production immediately. To maximize the value, we apply (28), (29) to (27), and substitute (12) into (27), the value of the leader is calculated as:

(30)

3.3. Equilibrium

Here, in order to examine impacts of pre-emptive competition, we assume that the roles of the leader and the follower are designated exogenously. The follower enters the market only after the leader has entered. This means that one firm is designated as the leader beforehand. So, the risk of pre-emption is eliminated, two firms can delay their investment to maximize their values. When the initial demand is sufficiently low, we suppose the leader (follower) select the optimal capacity , the investment threshold . Thus, the value

of the leader (follower) is denoted as . Similar to the above, must satisfy:

(31)

Combining (28) and (31), we have:

(32)

So, by substituting (32) into (12), the optimal threshold and the capacity of the follower are given by:

(33)

Comparing (14) and (32), Proposition 1 is obtained.

Proposition 1. The investment threshold of the designated leader is the same as that of the monopolist.

The designated leader has valuable option to defer investment at the optimal threshold of the monopolist as he need not face the risk of being preempted.

However, two firms are allowed to invest first in reality. This means that firm roles are endogenous. So, the risk of pre-emption exists. We assume that the initial demand level is sufficiently low, two firms are induced to delay their investment. When firm roles are endogenous, according to Fudenberg and Tirole [17] , if one firm intends to invest at the threshold first, the other firm will pre-empt it as long as the value of the firm is greater than that of the other firm. So the value is equal for both firms in equilibrium. Suppose that the value of the leader (follower), the optimal capacity , the investment threshold . So,

(34)

Proposition 2 describes the sequential equilibrium. For the proof of Proposition 2, see the Appendix.

Proposition 2. (sequential equilibrium). If the initial demand level is lower than, the equilibrium investment is sequential, the leader invests with capacity until the demand reaches, the follower invests with capacity until the demand reaches. Where, the optimal capacity of the leader is a unique solution of the equation:

(35)

the optimal capacity:

(36)

the optimal capacity and investment threshold of the follower:

(37)

Proposition 3, 4 describe the impacts of pre-emptive competition. The proofs are in Appendix.

Proposition 3. When the risk of pre-emption exists, the leader reduce its capacity to invest early, the follower increases its capacity to invest early. That is, , , , .

Proposition 4. If the initial demand level is lower than, the value of the leader is less than that of the designated leader, the value of the follower is larger than that of the designated follower. That is, ,.

4. Numerical Results Analysis

4.1. The Impacts of Pre-Emptive Competition

The subsection describes the impacts of pre-emptive competition on the firms. The parameters are as follows:

, , , , , ,.

Based on the given parameters, we calculate to obtain the optimal capacities and thresholds respectively as the roles of the firms are endogenous or exogenous:, , , , , , ,. We can see that, hold from the numerical results. This means that the leader will reduce production to speed up the investment due to fear of being pre-empted. Comparison of the numerical results, we find that, stand. This is because when the leader reduces production to invest ahead, the production in the market is not enough, the price is relatively high, the follower is willing to increase production to invest ahead. These results indicate pre-emptive competition makes the two firms to accelerate investment.

Figure 1 further shows the relationship between the values of the two firms as the roles are endogenous or exogenous. The numerical analysis is based on the assumptions that the initial demand is less than, the firms will wait until the optimal timing to enter the market. See Figure 1, the value of the designated leader is the largest, that of the leader is the second, that of the designated follower is the smallest. That is to say,. When the firm roles are designated, the designated follower is at a disadvantage in the game. The designated leader is dominant, he will invest at the optimal timing not considering the risk of pre-emption. So, the conclusion is intuitive.

So, Figure 1 suggests the conclusions of Proposition 3, 4.

4.2. Sensitivity Analysis

In the subsection, we perform a comparative static analysis, focusing on the impacts of different parameter values such as the Poisson jump process of intensity λ, the deterministic amplitude of the jumps θ, the volatility.

Table 1 illustrates the impacts of different values of λ. The parameters are as follows:, , , , , ,. The intensity λ measures the arrival probability of sudden events such as financial crisis or financial tsunami. When sudden events occur, the economy will be immersed in depression, a sudden decline in market demand. When λ increases, the leader will reduce its production to invest later, the follower will reduce its production to invest earlier first, then later. Increasing λ brings more risks which will make the leader more conservative. The investment threshold of the follower is non monotonic with

Figure 1. Values of the two firms.

λ. As we mentioned above, higher λ makes the investors reduce output to invest later. On the other hand, higher price which due to less output encourages the follower to invest earlier. As λ increases, the values of both the leader and the follower will decline.

Table 2 illustrates the impacts of different values of θ. The parameters are as follows:, , , , , ,. The deterministic amplitude of the jumps θ measures the level of the effect of the sudden events on investment environment. As θ decreases, both the leader and the follower will reduce production to invest later. Decreasing θ means worse investment environment. Thus, the values of both will decline.

Table 3 illustrates the impacts of different values of. The parameters are as follows:, , , , , ,. As increases, the uncertainties and risks linked with investment also increase. When the uncertainties and risks rise, both the leader and the follower will prefer to wait for better chance rather than now. So, they will increase production to invest later, the values of both will increase.

5. Conclusions

In this paper, we examine the impact of sudden events on the investment timing and production capacity decisions of a firm that faces competition. We obtain the investment equilibrium strategies.

Table 1. Impacts of different values of λ.

Table 2. Impacts of different values of θ.

Table 3. Impacts of different values of σ.

We find that pre-emptive competition and sudden events have great influence on investment decisions; pre-emptive competition makes firms accelerate investment. Higher uncertainty for market demand increases the values of both the leader and the follower. When sudden events occur more frequently or product demand declines in greater magnitude, the values of both firms will decline.

This paper considers the case of two firms. Consequently, a natural idea is to consider the case of a number of firms. Future research can also be concerned with the application of a different random process, e.g., arithmetic Brownian motion.

Acknowledgements

This research is supported by NSFC (71271127, 10971127).

References

  1. Smets, F. (1991) Exporting versus FDI: The Effect of Uncertainty, Irreversibilities and Strategic Interactions. Working Paper, Yale University, New Haven.
  2. Dixit, A. K. and Pindyck, R.S. (1994) Investment under Uncertainty. Princeton University Press, Princeton.
  3. Grenadier, S.R. (1996) The Strategic Exercise of Options: Development Cascades and Overbuilding in Real Estate Markets. The Journal of Finance, 51, 1653-1679. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1996.tb05221.x
  4. Weeds, H. (2002) Strategic Delay in a Real Options Model of R&D Competition. The Review of Economic Studies, 69, 729-747. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1467-937X.t01-1-00029
  5. Mason, R. and Weeds, H. (2010) Investment, Uncertainty and Pre-Emption. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 28, 278-287. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2009.09.004
  6. Jorion, P. (1988) On Jump Processes in the Foreign Exchange and Stock Markets. Review of Financial Studies, 1, 427- 445. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/1.4.427
  7. Bates, D.S. (1996) Jumps and Stochastic Volatility: Exchange Rate Processes Implicit in Deutsche Mark Options. Review of Financial Studies, 9, 69-107. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/9.1.69
  8. Merton, R.C. (1976) Option Pricing When Underlying Stock Returns Are Discontinuous. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 125-144. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(76)90022-2
  9. Kou, S.G. (2002) A Jump-Diffusion Model for Option Pricing. Management Science, 48, 1086-1101. http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.48.8.1086.166
  10. Mason, C.F. and Wilmot, N.A. (2014) Jump Processes in Natural Gas Markets. Energy Economics, 46, S69-S79. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2014.09.015
  11. Ko, C.-C., Lin, T.T. and Yang, C. (2011) The Venture Capital Entry Model on Game Options with Jump-Diffusion Process. International Journal of Production Economics, 134, 87-94. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2011.02.016
  12. Pereira, P.J. and Armada, M.R. (2013) Investment Decisions under Hidden Competition. Economics Letters, 121, 228- 231. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2013.07.029
  13. Pereira, P.J. and Rodrigues, A. (2014) Investment Decisions in Finite-Lived Monopolies. Journal of Economic Dyna- mics and Control, 46, 219-236. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2014.07.003
  14. Besanko, D., Doraszelski, U., Lu, L.X. and Satterthwaite, M. (2010) Lumpy Capacity Investment and Disinvestment Dynamics. Operations Research, 58, 1178-1193. http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/opre.1100.0823
  15. Jou, J.B. and Lee, T. (2008) Irreversible Investment, Financing, and Bankruptcy Decisions in an Oligopoly. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 43, 769-786. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0022109000004282
  16. Huisman, K. and Kort, P.M. (2013) Strategic Capacity Investment under Uncertainty. Tilburg University, Tilburg.
  17. Fudenberg, D. and Tirole, J. (1985) Preemption and Rent Equalization in the Adoption of New Technology. The Review of Economic Studies, 52, 383-401. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2297660

Appendix

The proof for Proposition 2:

When pre-emptive competition exists, the follower makes his decisions reacting to the capacity of the leader. According to (28), we can obtain (36). According to (12), we can obtain (37).

The value is the same for both firms at the threshold. Substitute into (13) and (30), we have:

Simplifying the above equation, we conclude that (35) stands and is a unique root of (35).

The proof for Proposition 3:

We proof that when, first.

(38)

Let, we have, , and if, then. So,. Thus, we conclude and. According to (38), we obtain that,.

Substitute into (35), we have. So,. Combining (12) and (28), Proposition 3 holds.

The proof for Proposition 4:

If, taking the first derivatives on (13) and (30) respectively:

. So, if, is a monotonically increas-

ing function of, is a monotonically decreasing function of. Because, we have Proposition 4 holds.