Theoretical Economics Letters
Vol.07 No.01(2017), Article ID:72710,12 pages
10.4236/tel.2017.71001

Optimal Vigilance Level and Hiring Illegal Immigrants

Munirul H. Nabin, Pasquale M. Sgro

Department of Economics, Deakin University, Geelong, Australia

Copyright © 2017 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution International License (CC BY 4.0).

http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/

Received: September 2, 2016; Accepted: December 9, 2016; Published: December 13, 2016

ABSTRACT

This paper assumes a Ricardian Economy and analyzes migration of illegal unskilled workers in a model of Cournot Duopoly where firms are producing homogenous and non-traded goods, and hiring illegal immigrants. The focus is on the behaviours of firms and the implications for the output, prices and employment of domestic workers in that industry. A two-stage simultaneous move game is set up: In Stage 1, for a given technology and vigilance level, each individual firm will decide whether to hire illegal immigrants. In Stage 2, each firm will choose the Cournot output level. Using this structure, we provide additional insights as to why firms hire illegal workers and what motivates these firms in their hiring practices. Furthermore the presence of illegal immigrants may create more employment for domestic workers and a social planner can be strategic in choosing optimal level of vigilance as we have shown that multiple solutions for optimal vigilance are possible and also Pareto ranked.

Keywords:

Illegal Immigrants, Vigilance, Cournot Competition, Welfare

1. Introduction

Illegal migrants are present in almost every developed as well as several underdeveloped countries. Examples include Canada, the European Union, India, Japan, South Africa and the USA. For example, in the United States, combined evidence from various sources suggests that there were at least 7 million unauthorized migrants at the time of the 2000 census, out of a total of 31 million foreign-born people in the country, who were not US citizens at the time of their birth. Of the unauthorized, an estimated 4.8 million were Mexican? [1] 1. A more recent figure has confirmed that the total estimated number of illegal immigrants in the US has increased to 12 million [2] .

Although the issue of whether illegal migrants enhance the welfare of a host country is debatable, most countries have adopted policies to halt the flow of illegal immigration [3] [4] [5] . Two common policies, which are used by most countries to halt the flow of illegal migrants, are (i) internal enforcement such as imposing sanctions on employers who hire illegal migrants that includes-a demand-side policy, and (ii) border enforce- ment-a supply-side policy. Note that the supply side immigration policy could also be influenced by the immigrant’s self-selection mechanism [6] .

Both of the above policies, employer sanction and border enforcement, along with the effects of illegal immigration have been extensively analyzed in the international trade literature [7] [8] [9] [10] . These analyses have generally taken place utilising perfectly competitive general equilibrium (hereafter GE) frameworks.

However, many industries that hire illegal migrants are operating under an oligopoly market structure. For example, The US meat-packer industry which predominantly hires illegal migrants operates under an oligopoly market structure where strategic interaction plays a crucial role [11] . The problem is so severe that one of the kosher meat-packing companies in Iowa, which had been charged for hiring illegal immigrants, and was fined so heavily that it filed for bankruptcy [12] . Recent evidence, as argued by Porter (2006), suggests that even though the US has declared an all-out war against illegal immigration by increasing the border enforcement budget, a closer examination reveals that the deterrent effect of the designed policy is small [13] [14] 2. Porter (2006) has argued that one of the main reasons for the continued ineffectiveness of the illegal immigration policy (policing) is that the work-place is virtually unpoliced3. This is due, in part, to political pressure not to police the work-place as it hurts employers.

Therefore, to analyze such industries, one needs to utilize a partial equilibrium framework. Despite the limitation of such a framework (compared to GE), it may provide more insights into the behaviour of an individual firm that operates under an oligopoly market structure and hires illegal migrants. This also plays a crucial role in the design and implementation of the demand-side policy of employer sanction in such a market structure. Thus our focus is on the role of vigilance and employer sanctions rather than the relative effectiveness of boarder enforcement versus employer sanctions.

Our paper is organised as follows: Section 2 provides the basic model set-up, Section 3 analyses welfare and determines the optimal vigilance level and Section 4 concludes.

2. Model

Preliminaries

We utilise the same set-up as Nabin and Sgro (2013) and their Lemma 1 below and Lemma 2 in the next section 3.1 for our analysis. There are two firms, 1 and 2 , operating in a Ricardian Economy where the only means of production is unskilled labour4. Each individual firm is producing non-traded homogenous goods q i , where i = { 1 , 2 } . The market demand function is P ( Q ) = A Q where Q is the total amount of output (i.e. Q = i = 1 2 q i ) produced by the two firms. An individual firm will maximize the following objective function:

max q i Π = [ P ( Q ) c i ] q i (1)

Here, c i > 0 is the cost of producing one unit of output. Assume that, for given technology T , an individual firm i needs l ^ T labour (assuming that 0 l ^ T 1 ) in order to produce one unit of output q i i.e. labour demand to produce one unit of output is l ^ T . We assume linear production technology where the labour demand for unit output is fixed for a given technology T 5.

The unskilled labour market consists of both domestic denoted by d and illegal immigrant workers, per unit of output denoted by h . It is also assumed that unskilled labour market is characterized by surplus labour and a binding minimum wage is in operation.

Each firm i has to pay the minimum wage w ¯ > 0 per unit of domestic worker d . Therefore, the cost of hiring a domestic worker by an individual firm i to produce one unit of output, denoted by c i d , is as follows:

c i d = w ¯ (2)

Alternatively, each individual firm can hire illegal migrants. The cost of hiring an illegal migrant h depends on: (i) the minimum wage, denoted by θ w ¯ , paid to illegal migrant where the parameter θ ( 0 , 1 ] . Without loss of generality, we assume that θ is given6. In the absence of vigilance and employer sanction, for any θ such that θ < 1 , h = l ^ T and an individual firm has an incentive to hire illegal immigrants only. However, in the case where both vigilance and employer sanction are present, h l ^ T and an individual firm has an incentive to hire both domestic and illegal workers such that h [ 0 , l ^ T ) .

The expected punishment cost of hiring an illegal migrant is denoted by p Z . The parameter Z ( > w ¯ ) is the punishment cost, or the employer sanction measured in monetary units, and p is the probability of being caught for hiring illegal migrants. The probability p depends on a given level of vigilance v , such that v [ 0 , v ¯ ] , and the number of illegal migrants per unit of output h (hired by an individual firm). Here, v ¯ is the highest level of vigilance. Let us consider p = [ α [ ϕ ( v ) h ] + ( 1 α ) ] . Here, α is the indicator parameter and p satisfies the following assumption:

Assumption 1

A. α = ( 1 if v [ 0 , v ¯ ) and h < l ^ T , 0 if v = v ¯ or / and h = l ^ T .

B. 0 ϕ ( v ) h 1 ; and v [ 0 , v ¯ ] the following is true: ϕ v ( v ) > 0 .

C. h > 0 , ϕ ( v ) h 0 as v 0 ; and v > 0 , ϕ ( v ) h 0 as h 0 .

Assumption 1 implies that an individual firm’s probability of being caught for hiring illegal immigrants depends on both the level of vigilance and the number of illegal immigrants hired. One might argue that both the type and number of illegal immigrants affect the probability of being caught. If the illegal immigrant is from the same ethnic group as the domestic worker, it is easier to blend into the workforce. On the other hand, if the illegal migrant looks different, it is much harder to blend in. For a given level of vigilance, the probability of being caught would be greater for the latter group than the former. The indicator parameter α incorporates this. If an individual firm hires all illegal immigrants from different ethnic backgrounds (i.e. h = l ^ T ) then probability of getting caught is 1 i.e. p = 1 . The probability of getting caught is also 1 if government chooses the highest level of vigilance ie v = v ¯ .

Firm i s unit cost of hiring an illegal migrant, denoted by c i h , is as follows:

c i h = θ w ¯ + ϕ ( v ) h Z . (3)

An individual firm has an incentive to hire illegal immigrant if the following condition is met7:

c i h c i d h ( 1 θ ) w ¯ ϕ ( v ) Z h * (4)

One of the implications of Equation (4) is as follows: for any given v > 0 , the cost of hiring labour for producing one unit of output will be as follows8:

c i = ( c ^ T d = w ¯ l ^ T for l ^ T h * , c ^ T d h = w ¯ [ l ^ T h * ( 1 θ ) ] for l ^ T > h * .

Indeed, the above expression reveals that there exists a non-monotonic relationship between the increased vigilance level and domestic job creations. Note that, If an individual firm chooses not to hire illegal migrants then the unit cost of hiring labour will be c i = c ^ 0 = w ¯ l ^ T .

Structure of the Game: In this game, an individual firm’s decision is taken in two stages:

Stage 1: In this stage, an individual firm will decide whether to hire illegal immigrants.

Stage 2: An individual firm will then choose its output level q i , i.e., each firm is engaging in Cournot-Nash Competition.

The above game can be solved by backward induction. One can easily solve Stage 2 of this game. Since each firm is facing Cournot-Nash Competition, one obtains the following standard Cournot results by using Equation (1):

q 1 * ( c 1 , c 2 ) = 1 3 [ A 2 c 1 + c 2 ] and Π 1 * = [ q 1 * ( c 1 , c 2 ) ] 2 q 2 * ( c 1 , c 2 ) = 1 3 [ A 2 c 2 + c 1 ] and Π 2 * = [ q 2 * ( c 1 , c 2 ) ] 2 P * = A q 1 * ( c 1 , c 2 ) q 2 * ( c 1 , c 2 ) C S ( c 1 , c 2 ) = 1 2 { [ q 1 * ( c 1 , c 2 ) ] 2 + [ q 2 * ( c 1 , c 2 ) ] 2 } + q 1 * ( c 1 , c 2 ) q 2 * ( c 1 , c 2 ) P S ( c 1 , c 2 ) = [ q 1 * ( c 1 , c 2 ) ] 2 + [ q 2 * ( c 1 , c 2 ) ] 2 W ( c 1 , c 2 ) = 3 2 { [ q 1 * ( c 1 , c 2 ) ] 2 + [ q 2 * ( c 1 , c 2 ) ] 2 } + q 1 * ( c 1 , c 2 ) q 2 * ( c 1 , c 2 ) W ( c 1 , c 2 | c 1 = c 2 ) = [ q 1 * ( c 1 , c 2 | c 1 = c 2 ) + q 2 * ( c 1 , c 2 | c 1 = c 2 ) ] 2 (5)

where the “*” signifies the equilibrium values and C S , P S and W stand for consumer surplus, producer surplus and welfare, respectively, W = C S + P S at equilibrium.

An individual firm i will find that hiring illegal immigrants reduces the value of c i because they are paid less than the domestic workers9. In this case, solving Stage 1 of this game, involves a Nash equilibrium where each firm hires illegal migrants. However, in the presence of interior vigilance level v , the above result may not hold. Therefore, one needs to characterize the role of v in determining the value of c i . This is crucial not only for solving the Stage 1 of our game, but also to the understanding of how firms behave when they are hiring illegal immigrants. Indeed, Nabin and Sgro (2013) have developed the following Lemma :

Lemma 1. For any given technology such that l ^ T > h * , an individual firm finds the strategy of hiring illegal immigrants profitable at equilibrium and such a strategy is also dominant over the strategy of not hiring illegal immigrants. However, if l ^ T h * then no individual firm is hiring illegal immigrants.

Proof. See Nabin and Sgro (2013) for proof [18] .

For given technology T and l ^ T > h * , one can also derive the total demand for illegal immigrants which is as follows:

E d h = h * Q * = h * 2 3 [ A l ^ T + h * ( 1 θ ) ]

where h * is the demand for an illegal immigrant to produce one unit of output, and Q * is the aggregate level of output of a given industry.

3. Analysis

3.1. Welfare Analysis

Conditions for an individual firm hiring both domestic workers and illegal immigrants, or hiring only domestic workers have been derived (i.e. Lemma 2). To complete our analysis we need to analyze the welfare of an industry when an individual firm has an incentive to hire illegal immigrants for a given technology. Without loss of generality and to keep our analysis simple, we normalize w ¯ = 1 , this also implies that Z > 1 (this follows from our earlier discussion).

This section considers two welfare criteria to analyze the welfare of an industry. Our concern is not about social welfare both the effects on certain industries with imperfectly competitive market structures.

Criterion 1: This criterion simply considers Marshallian surplus to examine the welfare of the given industry. For a given technology T , if no one hires illegal immi- grants, the total surplus will be as follows (from Equation (5)):

W 0 T = 4 9 [ A l ^ T ] 2 (6)

Similarly, for given technology T , if an individual firm hires illegal immigrants, the total surplus will be as follows:

W h T = ( 4 9 [ A l ^ T + h * ( 1 θ ) ] 2 l ^ T > h * 4 9 [ A l ^ T ] 2 l ^ T h * (7)

Criterion 2: Our second criterion emphasizes the employment level of domestic workers. For given technology T , if no one hires illegal migrants, total employment for domestic unskilled workers, in this particular industry, will be as follows (from Equation (5)):

E 0 T = l ^ T i = 1 2 q i * = l ^ T 2 3 [ A l ^ T ] (8)

Similarly, for given technology T , if an individual firm hires illegal migrants, total employment for domestic unskilled workers, in this particular industry, will be as follows :

E h T = ( ( l ^ T h * ) 2 3 [ A l ^ T + h * ( 1 θ ) ] , l ^ T > h * l ^ T 2 3 [ A l ^ T ] , l ^ T h * (9)

By using the Equations (6), (7), (8) and (9), we develop the following proposition:

Proposition 1. θ ( 0 , 1 ] , the following will be true for a given industry:

A. Given technology l ^ T such that if l ^ T > h * , then hiring illegal migrants is welfare enhancing as W h T W 0 T .

B. (i) l ^ T > h * and l ^ T < A 2 l ^ T ϕ ( v ) Z 1 ϕ ( v ) Z , θ * such that θ < θ * then E h T E 0 T and if θ > θ * then E h T < E 0 T .

(ii) However, l ^ T > h * and A > 2 l ^ T ϕ ( v ) Z 1 ϕ ( v ) Z , then E h T < E 0 T .

C. If l ^ T h * then W h T = W 0 T and E h T = E 0 T will be true.

Proof. Please see the Appendix.

The above proposition tells us that, contrary to conventional wisdom, hiring illegal immigrants is not necessarily detrimental to welfare or domestic job creation for domestic workers in a given industry. Figure 1 illustrates Propositions 1 A and 1 B(i) for the parameter values A = 0.59 , l ^ T = 0.5 , ϕ ( v ) Z = 3 and θ [ 0 , 1 ] . In Figure 1, (a) illustrates the welfare of an economy, whereas (b) illustrates the domestic job creation in a given industry. Clearly, when θ < 0.8 and each firm is hiring illegal

(a) (b)

Figure 1. (a) Welfare of an industry and (b) Domestic Job Creation.

immigrants, employment opportunities for domestic workers are higher than when no firm hires illegal immigrants. Given the production technology, for a lower value of θ , a firm is able to hire more illegal immigrants only by hiring more domestic workers. This follows from the non-monotonic unit cost of production. The fact is that, in the presence of vigilance and employer sanction and for any θ such that θ < 1 , both illegal workers and domestic workers become complementary factors10. Therefore, it is interesting to analyze the role of vigilance level and firms’ hiring behaviour regarding domestic workers.

Our result is consistent with the earlier empirical findings of [19] where they used the Leontief production function to estimate the effect of illegal Mexican immigrants on native workers.

3.2. Optimal Vigilance Level

To understand the effect of an increased vigilance level on employment opportunities of native workers, we rewrite Equation (9) as follows:

E h T = a d Q * l ^ T > h * where a d = l ^ h * and Q * = 2 3 [ A l ^ T + h * ( 1 θ ) ] (10)

By differentiating Equation (10) with respect to v we get:

Δ E h T Δ v = Δ a d Δ v Q * + Δ Q * Δ v a d Δ E h T v Δ v E h T = Δ a d v Δ v E h T Q * + Δ Q * v Δ v E h T a d ( dividebothsideby v E h T ) Δ E h T v Δ v E h T = Δ a d v Δ v a d + Δ Q * v Δ v Q * ( follows from Equation ( 10 ) ) η E h T , v = η a d , v | η Q * , v | (11)

Here, η E h T , v = Δ E h T v Δ v E h T , η a d , v = Δ a d v Δ v a d > 0 and η Q * , v = Δ Q * v Δ v Q * < 0 .

Equation (11) helps us to develop the following proposition:

Proposition 2. For given technology T and l ^ T > h * , the following will be true:

A. If η a d , v > | η Q * , v | then η E h T , v > 0 .

B. If η a d , v = | η Q * , v | then η E h T , v = 0 .

C. If η a d , v < | η Q * , v | then η E h T , v < 0 .

Proof. The proof mainly follows from Equation (11).

Proposition 2 states that an increase in the vigilance level will not necessarily lead to an increase in employment opportunities for native workers. Indeed, there is a non- monotonic relationship between the vigilance level and employment of native workers. An increase in the vigilance level has two effects: (i) it will reduce the value of h * , and increase the value of a d . This occurs because an increase in the vigilance level will increase the cost of hiring illegal migrants to produce one unit of output, hence a firm has less incentive to hire illegal immigrants; and (ii) it will reduce the aggregate output level, Q * . Since total employment for native workers is also proportional to aggregate output level, it will also fall. Clearly, these two effects are moving in opposite directions. Therefore, the total employment opportunities for native workers due to increased vigilance, depend on which effect will dominate. Indeed, Proposition 2 explains this in terms of the elasticities of total employment (for native workers), E h T , a d and aggregate output level Q * with respect to v . Figure 2 illustrates these two effects more clearly.

Figure 2. Employment opportunities for native workers and vigilance level.

Figure 2 illustrates the relationship between the vigilance level v and employment for native workers E h T using a four quadrants diagram. The fourth quadrant illustrates the negative relationship between v and h * (from condition (4)), the first and second quadrants illustrate the positive relationship between: (i) h * and Q * (from Equation (10)) (ii) Q * and E h T (from Equation (10)) respectively. Finally, the third quadrant illustrates the non-monotonic relationship between E h T and v (from Proposition 2). For a given level of vigilance level v 1 , the corresponding h * will be h 1 * as shown in the fourth quadrant. Thus h 1 * will lead us to output level Q 1 * , which is shown in the first quadrant. Given a d , this Q 1 * leads us to employment level E 1 T shown in the second quadrant. In the third quadrant, E 1 T translates to vigilance level v 1 which is shown as a . Suppose v 1 increases to v 2 , as a result h 1 * falls to h 2 * (shown in the fourth quadrant) which eventually reduces aggregate output level Q 1 * to Q 2 * (shown in the first quadrant). Furthermore, a decrease in h * from h 1 * to h 2 * --will also increase the value of a d to either a 1 d or a 2 d or a 3 d (shown in the second quadrant) and this effect, along with falling output level, will lead to either a decrease in total employment to E 2 T , or no change in E 1 T or an increase in total employment E 3 T (from Proposition 2)11.

The crucial point of the above diagram is that an increase in the vigilance level will not necessarily increase the total employment of native workers. Indeed, it might reduce the total employment for native workers because of the non-monotonic relationship between the vigilance level and the employment level for native workers (from our Proposition 2). The non-monotonic relationship also raises the possibility of the existence of v * such that it will maximize the employment opportunities for native workers. The following equation confirms this:

max v E h T = a d Q * v * η a d , v = | η Q * , v | (12)

The condition (12) leads to the following proposition:

Lemma 2. Multiple solutions for v * are possible. The following summarizes the result12:

A. There exists a corner solution where v * = v ¯ .

B. θ ( 0 , 1 ) and l ^ T < A < 2 l ^ T ( 2 ( 1 θ ) 2 ϕ ( v ¯ ) Z + θ l ^ T ) , there also exists an interior solution for v * such that v * = ϕ 1 ( 2 ( 1 θ ) 2 w ¯ Z [ l ^ T ( 2 θ ) A ] ) v * * < v ¯ .

Proof. Please see the Appendix

The above Lemma implies that if an individual social planner has an objective to maximize job opportunities for native workers then either she can choose v ¯ or v * * , where the former is the vigilance level for zero tolerance of illegal migrants and the latter the vigilance level that allows some illegal migrants. However, the vigilance level v * * is Pareto dominant over v ¯ . Even though both levels of vigilance maximize the job opportunities for native workers, it is the latter which gives us relatively more welfare (from Proposition 1 A). Thus our model suggests that there exists two sets of policies regarding the optimal vigilance level and these are K 1 = { v ¯ , W L } and K 2 = { v * * , W H } ; where v ¯ > v * * and W L < W H ; and K 2 is Pareto dominant over K 1 .

4. Conclusion

In this paper a Ricardian model has been used to examine the effects of illegal immigrants on firms in a Cournot Oligopoly model. A game theory framework has been used and internal vigilance has been analyzed as a policy to curb illegal immi- grants. We have provided additional insights as to why firms hire illegal workers and what motivates these firms in their hiring practices. Furthermore, we have demon- strated that multiple solutions exist for the optimal level of vigilance. There exists a vigilance level with non-zero tolerance of illegal immigrants which is as effective, in creating industry employment opportunities for native workers, as the vigilance level with zero tolerance of illegal immigration. Finally, we have introduced a voting model to show which level of vigilance will be chosen.

Acknowledgements

We thank the editor and the referee for their comments.

Cite this paper

Nabin, M.H. and Sgro, P.M. (2017) Optimal Vigilance Level and Hiring Illegal Immigrants. Theoretical Economics Letters, 7, 1-12. http://dx.doi.org/10.4236/tel.2017.71001

References

  1. 1. The California Farm Labor Force: Overview and Trends. National Agricultural Workers Survey (2003-2004). US Department of Labor, 2004.

  2. 2. Knowledge@Wharton. On the Fence: Are Illegal Immigrants Good or Bad for the US Economy? 2007. http://knowledge.wharton.upenn.edu/article.cfm?articleid=1754

  3. 3. Bhagwati. J.N. (1998) Comment on Borjas Michigan University Conference, Washington DC.

  4. 4. Borjas. G.J. (1995) The Economic Benefits from Immigration. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9, 3-22. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.9.2.3

  5. 5. Borjas, G.J. and Katz, L.F. (2005) The Evolution of the Mexican Born Workforce in the United States. NBER Working Paper, No. 11281.

  6. 6. Bianchi, M. (2013) Immigration Policy and Self-Selecting Migrants. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 15, 1-23. https://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12007

  7. 7. Bhagwati, J.N. (1982) Directly Unproductive, Profit-Seeking (DUP) Activities. Journal of Political Economy, 90, 988-1002. https://doi.org/10.1086/261104

  8. 8. Bond, E. and Chen, T-J. (1987) The Welfare Effects of Illegal Immigration. Journal of International Economics, 23, 315-328. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-1996(87)90058-4

  9. 9. Djajic, S. (1999) Dynamics of Immigration Control. Journal of Population Economics, 12, 45-61. https://doi.org/10.1007/s001480050090

  10. 10. Ethier, W. (1986) Illegal Immigration: The Host-Country Problem. American Economic Review, 76, 56-71.

  11. 11. Dyer, J. (2006) Meatpacking Industry Has a Long History of Reliance on Immigrant Laborers. The Fort Collins Weekly, 1-5.

  12. 12. Preston, J. (2008) Large Iowa Meatpacker in Illegal Immigrant Raid Files for Bankruptcy. The New York Times. http://www.nytimes.com/2008/11/06/us/06immig.html

  13. 13. Hanson, G. (2006) Illegal Migration from Mexico to the United States. Journal of Economic Literature, 44, 869-924. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.44.4.869

  14. 14. Porter, E. (2006) The Search for Illegal Immigrants Stops at the Workplace. The New York Times. http://www.nytimes.com/2006/03/05/business/yourmoney/05view.html

  15. 15. Gathmann, C. (2006) Effects of Enforcement on Illegal Markets: Evidence from Migrants Smuggling along the Southwestern Border. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 1926-1941. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2008.04.006

  16. 16. Broeders, D. and Engberson, G. (2007) The Fight against Illegal Migration: Identification Policies and Immigrants’ Counter-Strategies. American Behavioral Scientist, 50, 1592-1609. https://doi.org/10.1177/0002764207302470

  17. 17. Clark, G. (1991) Yields per Acre in English Agriculture, 1250-1860: Evidence from Labour Inputs. The Economic History Review, 44, 445-460. https://doi.org/10.2307/2597538

  18. 18. Nabin, M.H. and Sgro, P.M. (2013) Illegal Immigration, Technology Adoption and Welfare. Asia-Pacific Journal of Accounting and Economics, 20, 183-198. https://doi.org/10.1080/16081625.2012.738803

  19. 19. Bean, F.D., Lowell, B.L. and Taylor, L.J. (1988) Undocumented Mexican Immigrants and the Earnings of Other Workers in the United States. Demography, 25, 35-52. https://doi.org/10.2307/2061476

  20. 20. Passel, J.S. and Cohn, D. (2009) A Portrait of Unauthorized Immigrants in the United States. Report, Pew Hispanic Center, Washington DC.

  21. 21. Grossman, J.B. (1984) Illegal Immigrants and Domestic Employment. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 37, 240-251. https://doi.org/10.1177/001979398403700206

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

(A) If l ^ T > h * then from Equations (6) and (7), one can show that W h T W 0 T as long as h * ( 1 θ ) 0 , which is true for all θ ( 0 , 1 ] . (B) From Equations (8) and (9) one can calculate Δ E = E h T E 0 T . By putting Δ E = 0 , one can solve for θ and the

solution is: θ = { 1 } , { 1 1 2 l ^ T ϕ ( v ) Z + 1 2 4 l ^ T ϕ ( v ) Z + ( l ^ T ϕ ( v ) Z ) 2 4 A ϕ ( v ) Z } . Since d Δ E d θ | θ = 1 = 2 3 ϕ ( v ) Z ( A l ^ T ) > 0 , this implies that at θ = 1 , Δ E cuts the horizontal axis

from below. Therefore, at other feasible solutions of θ , Δ E must cut the horizontal axis from above. Then denote this θ as θ * . This implies that for any θ such that θ < θ * , Δ E > 0 E h T > E 0 T . For feasibility of such

θ * = 1 1 2 l ^ T ϕ ( v ) Z + 1 2 4 l ^ T ϕ ( v ) Z + ( l ^ T ϕ ( v ) Z ) 2 4 A ϕ ( v ) Z , it must lie between 0 and 1 . This gives us the condition: l ^ T < A 2 l ^ T ϕ ( v ) Z 1 ϕ ( v ) Z . Therefore, if A > 2 l ^ T ϕ ( v ) Z 1 ϕ ( v ) Z , then the only feasible solution for θ will be 1 . Since Δ E cuts the

horizontal axis from below at θ = 1 , therefore, in this case Δ E < 0 E h T < E 0 T . (C) This proof follows mainly from Lemma 2. Lemma 2 states that no firm will hire illegal migrants if l ^ T h * . Therefore, in the presence of illegal migrants, W h T = W 0 T and E h T = E 0 T .

Proof of Lemma 2

(A) From condition (12) and with the help of Equation (10), one can explicitly solve for v * , which is as follows:

ϕ ( v * ) = 2 ( 1 θ ) 2 Z [ l ^ T ( 2 θ ) A ] v * = ϕ 1 ( 2 ( 1 θ ) 2 w ¯ Z [ l ^ T ( 2 θ ) A ] ) (13)

For feasibility of v * , we need the condition 0 < v * < v ¯ h be satisfied. This requires θ < 1 (which is true by our assumption), l ^ T < A < 2 l ^ T θ l ^ T and

l ^ T < A < 2 l ^ T ( 2 ( 1 θ ) 2 ϕ ( v ¯ ) Z + θ l ^ T ) . Here, the binding condition is l ^ T < A < 2 l ^ T ( 2 ( 1 θ ) 2 ϕ ( v ¯ ) Z + θ l ^ T ) .

(B) Assumption 1 tells us that if v = v ¯ then p = 1 . This implies that if v = v ¯ then h * = 0 . If so then v = v ¯ implies that η a d , v = | η Q * , v | = 0 (follows from Equation (10)). Therefore, v * = v ¯ satisfies condition 12.

NOTES

1It can also be a very divisive issue in many countries as recent examples in France, UK and the USA show.

2 [15] argues that illegal immigrants can also reduce their chances of being caught by hiring smugglers, who are often called coyotes.

3On the other hand, internal enforcement has proven very effective in northern European countries such as Germany and the Netherlands [16] .

4We are considering a very simple production structure. Other factors of production such as capital, could be added but will unnecessarily complicate the model.

5Though the limitations of linear technology are known, this assumption can be justified by the historical evidence, at least in English agricultural production as found by [17] . Furthermore, this assumption also implies that domestic workers and illegal immigrants are perfect substitutes for each other.

6Alternatively, one can think that θ represents the level of exploitation of an illegal worker of an industry i.e. an industry with high moral has high value of θ hence less exploitation and vice versa. Each individual firm in that industry operates with this industry's level of θ because of competition.

7Note that the total cost minimization problem of hiring labour per unit of output will be as follows: min { h } = [ θ w ¯ + ϕ ( v ) h ] h + [ l ^ T h ] w ¯ h = ( 1 θ ) w ¯ 2 ϕ ( v ) Z h ^ * * . However, an individual firm finds it profitable to hire more illegal immigrants h as long as any h h * . Since h ^ * * < h * , the only binding condition will be h * .

8For more details, please see [18] .

9Illegal immigrants have less market power because of their illegal status.

10Note that E h T = a d Q * , where a d = l ^ h * and Q * = 2 3 [ A l ^ T + h * ( 1 θ ) ] . A lower value of θ will increase Q * but reduce a d and, if the effect of an increased Q * is dominant over the effect of reduced a d , it will lead to an outcome where more jobs are created for native workers.

11Our findings are consistent with the empirical evidence of [20] and the simulation work of [21] where they find that hiring more illegal immigrants may lead to more domestic job creations.

12We assume that inverse of ϕ ( v ) exists and these multiple solutions must satisfy the second order condition ( θ ( 0 , 1 ) ) : d 2 E h T d v 2 = 2 ( 1 θ ) 3 [ ϕ ( v ) ] 2 Z ϕ ( v ) [ ϕ ( v ) 2 ( 1 θ ) 2 [ φ ( v ) ] 2 Z ( 2 + θ ) ] ( 1 θ ) 2 [ ϕ ( v ) ] 2 Z ( ϕ ( v ) ϕ ( v ) ) < 0 , whichistrueaslongas ϕ ( v ) 0 or ( ϕ ( v ) ϕ ( v ) ) > 0 holds . .